• A Fool’s Paradise?

    The pre-election, headline-grabbing, so-called “rock-star economy” may be less in evidence today, but there is still a good deal of self-congratulation about an annual GDP growth-rate of over 3%. There is general agreement that the New Zealand economy is doing pretty well, particularly when compared with what is happening elsewhere.

    It is only when we look behind the headline figure that doubts begin to emerge. Unpacking the figures and the trends is an important corrective to unjustified optimism.

    First, the current growth rate – a welcome relief from an unnecessarily protracted and slow recovery from recession – owes very little to merits of our own or to the way we have managed our economy. We emerged relatively unscathed from the Global Financial Crisis largely because of the stability of our Australian-owned banks and the buoyancy of our major export markets in Australia and China – both powerful and welcome factors but well beyond our control.

    The belated post-GFC stimulus to our economy came from another factor beyond our control and one which on other grounds we could well have done without – the Christchurch earthquake. A government that had set its face against using its powers to get the economy moving again – indeed, that had focused on reducing its own spending so that the economy as a whole was smaller than it need have been – found its hand forced by a natural disaster.

    No one doubts that the Christchurch re-build has been a major factor in lifting economic activity, particularly in the construction industry. We would not have had that stimulus to spending, employment and investment if the government had been left to its own devices.

    And much of our current optimism rests on a 2014 surge in international commodity prices, particularly for dairy products. Again, we are the beneficiaries but can claim little credit for it, and its effect already seems in any case to have been short-lived.

    A fourth factor that has lifted our economy and encouraged a spending spree is the asset inflation in the Auckland housing market, something that is a function of the banks’ willingness to go on creating new credit to lend on house purchase rather than of government policy. Indeed, the government professes itself to be unhappy with what is happening – and the Reserve Bank agrees that it is a problem, not a success.

    These factors that underpin and explain our relative success do not in any case come without a price. The increased lending by our banks, for example, simply adds to the billions of dollars in bank profits that are repatriated every year to Australia and that accordingly enlarge the burden on our foreign payments balance.

    The consumer spending spree makes inevitable a worsening of our perennial trade deficit, as we suck in more imports to meet our insistence on spending five cents in the dollar more than we earn.

    The prices people must now pay for Auckland housing must come from somewhere. They are not matched by any increase in real output and therefore reflect new money created by the banks and placed in the hands of existing home-owners at the expense of those who can’t afford to own their own homes, so that the inequality gap is thereby widened.

    The rise in dairy prices throws the spotlight on our increasingly dangerous dependence on a single commodity and on the Chinese market, carrying with it the risk that we are gradually being absorbed into a greater Chinese economy.

    But it is when we look to the future that the doubts really begin to grow. The government makes great play of its efforts to reduce its own deficit, without apparently concerning itself at all with the deficit that really matters – that of the country as a whole.

    How many of those who are inclined to congratulate the government on its prudence in “reducing the deficit” understand that we continue as a country to live well beyond our means and that the current consumer boom can only make that deficit worse?

    How many understand that the government deficit is only a small part of a much wider picture – that of an economy that cannot pay its way – and is in any case virtually inevitable for as long as we have a substantial foreign payments deficit?

    How many understand that the current emphasis on high interest rates and an overvalued dollar make it impossible for us to earn enough to pay our way? Or that the price we pay for the continued foreign payments deficit is that we must sell more assets and borrow more as a country to make up the gap – that we are quite literally spending away our future?

    Do we understand that, despite all the talk about broadening our economic base, we are more dependent than ever on the price of a single commodity and that our power of self-government is being constantly eroded as we become more dependent on just one customer for that commodity and as more and more of our economy passes in to foreign ownership?

    Should we not ask – is New Zealand the paradise we think it to be, or is it becoming a paradise for fools?

    Bryan Gould

    21 March 2015

     

  • Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 9

    Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government

    By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards

     

    Part 9 Further Proposals and a Conclusion

     

    The Wage and Salaries Increases Act

     

    One of the main, and perhaps – to western eyes – most surprising features of

    Japanese Prime Minister Shinzo Abe’s re-introduction of Shimomuran

    economics is his attempt to ensure that there is a rise in Japanese wages.

    In marked contrast to Coalition government’s determination to drive down

    wages here, he well understands that higher wages are an important way of

    raising demand in an economy which is intent on stimulating economic

    activity – hence his implication that the advantage of relatively cheap

    investment finance will be made available only to those firms that already

    pay, or are willing to undertake to pay in the future, a proper level of

    wages to their workforce.

    An incoming Labour government should take a similar stance, with positive

    policies for a greater share of national income by working people. In

    particular, there should be an immediate rise in the minimum wage rate to

    £8 an hour and an annual incomes and salaries growth target equal to the

    estimated rate of inflation plus the estimated rate of growth plus 2% for the

    first five years of the Labour Government. This, in the context of the other

    policies here proposed, will spread effective purchasing power throughout

    the economy and move all families out of poverty within the lifetime of this

    government. Zero-hours contracts should be made illegal in the UK. The

    disability and unemployment benefits system will so far as possible be uprated

    to the levels which would have obtained if the Coalition Government

    had never existed.

    A second part of wage legislation will be enacted to provide that future

    wage and salary increases will be divided, with the increases due to the

    estimated annual rate of inflation paid weekly or monthly and the

    estimated growth component paid as a lump sum every 1st November. This

    measure will ensure the growth of real wages and limit inflation, and

    provide earners with lump sum funds, which research has shown are more

    likely to be saved, which in turn will increase the emergency funds of

    families for holidays or to meet unexpected expenses.

    It will also usefully increase the saving of British families, and will, in our restructured financial

    system, increase bank funds for industry. That measure has proved very

    effective in Japan, where it may have been another policy initiative

    originating from the Japanese master economist Osamu Shimomura, and we

    think it will be as effective in the UK as it was in Japan.

     

    Improvements in The Machinery of Government

     

    A review of the dominant and self-interested role played in the British

    economy by the major banks leaves little room for surprise at the fact that

    the various initiatives to support a British economic revival have all failed.

    George Brown’s National Enterprise Board, the Industrial Re-Organisation

    Corporation, and the more recent suggestion of a National Investment Bank,

    all had and have one factor in common – they were inevitably small,

    central, initiatives depending upon the co-operation and goodwill of the

    Clearing Banks to allow them to work. Not surprisingly, over the last

    century and a half, the British Clearing Banks have never had any interest in

    permitting the survival of any organisation that could grow to challenge

    their virtual monopoly and have ensured that such experiments did not

    survive.1

    The proposals above for the reform of the banking system will go a

    long way towards remedying this situation and allowing genuine reforms to

    take effect. If, for any reason, the banks succeed again in frustrating the

    flow of lending for investment purposes to industry, it would certainly be

    worth looking again at a National Investment Bank which would ensure that

    such an objective was met, with that national bank having direct links to

    the Local Community Interest Banks.

    Finally, there is one additional change

    in the machinery of Government that should be put into place.

     

    The Economic Planning Agency

     

    An Economic Planning Agency (EPA) will be set up in the Office of the Prime

    Minister to fulfil the following goals:

    – to provide competent, timely and accurate advice to the government on

    how best to achieve the developing government objectives of increasing

    ______________________________________________________________

    economic growth, managing inflation, and making due provision for the

    impact of environmental changes on UK resources

    – to report upon the locality and potential of British businesses, particularly

    with regard to the development of the UK as a green economy

    – to identify and recommend potential and emerging innovations and the

    location of key knowledge-based growth hubs in the economy

    – to provide a monthly report upon the outcomes of the regional, national

    and local investments

    – to calculate and comment on, as it may see fit, the capital-output ratios

    and other key factors in the economic development of the country

    – to identify blockages in the free flow of investment funding for national

    and other viable projects, particularly with regard to national sea

    defences and the investments required to accelerate the movement into a

    greener economy

    – to provide an Annual Economic Survey of Britain, summarising the

    economic state of the nation and acting to improve the practical

    economic understanding of key industries, and

    – to report as regularly as it sees fit upon the results of various Government

    initiatives and projects, particularly with regard to

    – Green energy generation

    – The safeguarding of national resources against rising sea levels and

    extreme weather events

    – The improvement of national education and research and

    development facilities and

    – Other emerging issues which the EPA wish to bring to the

    Government’s attention.

    These new institutions will mirror the more competent SME funding

    arrangements and other existing industrial funding arrangements in

    Germany. These new banks will be guaranteed by government, as in fact all

    banks are in the last resort. There can be no foreign objection to the British

    Government taking steps to ensure that British domestic industry has access

    to financial facilities, similar to those that have existed, and which

    continue to exist, to fund foreign industry abroad. Given access to

    equivalent funding sources, we are confident that British invention will flow

    through to factory floor innovation and British industry will no longer lose

    its place in the world and will flourish through the fresh opportunities made

    available to it.

     

    Conclusion

     

    It is that fresh economic understanding that should enable an incoming

    Labour Government to reshape and reform the future of Britain. The

    objective of that Government’s economic policy should be the restoration

    of a civilised and progressive Britain where all of its people are free from

    want, excellently educated, and achieving their full potential within a

    much more prosperous and fairer society. Britain’s place in the world as an

    innovative, highly developed manufacturing economy operating at the

    leading edge of invention and innovation must be re-built. The fruits of that

    success should be more equitably distributed, not only as a matter of social

    justice and to secure a more integrated, happier and healthier society, but

    also as a stimulus and contributor to continuing economic success.

     

    1 For some of the methods used, see the Henley School of Management

    Paper by Peter Scott and Lucy Newton “Jealous monopolists? British banks

    and responses to the Macmillan Gap during the 1930s” which is at http://

    www.reading.ac.uk/web/FILES/management/036.pdf

     

    © Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015

     

  • Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 8

    Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government

    By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards

     

    Part 8: The Re-Establishment of British Banks Along Four Main Functional

    Lines

     

    As previously remarked, the continuation of the existing banking

    arrangements, in which the merchant bank gambling function is integrated

    within the rest of the banking business, is – as Mervyn King has regularly warned

    – not a safe way for the British economy to proceed. A major re-structuring

    of the British Banking sector is required, so that each bank is required to decide

    whether its primary function is that of a retail bank, a mortgage and

    consumer credit bank, a merchant bank or a local community investment

    credit bank.

    Retail banks will collect local savings and provide a banking service to local

    people and industry, providing the money-handling service which enables

    wages and salaries to be paid and all other transactions between buyer and

    seller to be carried out. Retail banks will be encouraged, if they wish, to

    develop close relationships with local industry (as is the norm in Germany)

    and to develop an informed view of the prospects of their local enterprises.

    Retail banks with many local branches will be invited to consider becoming

    local SME investment credit loan banks as they wish. Local authorities will

    be invited to consider setting up Local Authority Banks to help support their

    economic development. Government guarantees will be available for the

    savings and credit deposits in retail banks of up to £200,000 per individual,

    but it is very unlikely such guarantees would ever be required.

     

    Investment credit banks will have the primary purpose of extending long –

    term loans at an interest rate of 4% pa over terms of between ten and

    twenty years to British-based SMEs. These banks will have the ability to rediscount

    their business loans up to the official re-discount limits set under

    the “window guidance” at the Bank of England. Such banks will be

    completely backed by government. SMEs and other companies taking out

    loans and the personnel employed by these companies will be expected to

    change their bank so that the loans granted, the wealth created in company

    accounts and the wages paid will all initially, and perhaps ultimately, be in

    the loan-providing bank. Savings kept in investment credit banks will have a

    structured rate of interest so that short-term one-year savings will have an

    interest rate of 1% and savings over five years will be offered an interest

    rate of inflation plus 1% and thus effectively would be better than inflation-proofed.

     

    Mortgage and consumer credit banks would have the major function of

    providing mortgages or consumer credit at relatively low rates of interest.

    The mortgage section and consumer credit section of any bank should be

    legally operated as a distinct entity within any bank which provides any

    other functions. Government guarantees will be available for the savings

    and credit deposits in mortgage and retail banks of up to £100,000 per

    individual, but again it is very unlikely such guarantees would ever be

    required.

     

    Merchant banks will exist as entirely separate free-standing institutions not

    associated with any other bank and may attract such savings as may be

    commensurate with their level of risk. The risks of complete loss of savings

    must be clearly explained to merchant bank savers, and no government

    guarantee for any savings placed in a merchant bank will be available.

    Merchant banks will be obliged to keep reserves, probably in the range of

    10%-20% of total bank assets, commensurate with the gambling risks they

    undertake, as determined by the Financial Services Authority.

     

    These measures would go a long way towards constructing a banking system

    that provides proper security and guarantees to savers, that truly serves

    the public interest and that in particular provides much-needed investment

    finance to Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises.

     

    © Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015

  • Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 7

    Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government

    By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards

     

    Part 7: The Community Interest Bank Key to Local SME Development

     

    Despite the provision to the banks of huge sums by way of Quantitative

    Easing, very little of that money has found its way into bank lending for

    productive investment. The excuses trotted out for this failure include the

    age-old claim by British banks that the comparatively low level of their

    lending to business does not evidence any reluctance to do so, but merely a

    shortage of demand – or, to put it another way, a shortage of suitable

    projects on which to lend. But no sense of this can be made unless we

    know the terms on which the banks are offering to lend.

    And that is precisely, of course, what we are not usually allowed to know.

    The banks have traditionally been very coy about the terms they offer. But

    the Bank of England has recently required the British Banking system to

    make returns showing the extent and the terms of lending to enterprises.

    The information that is now available shows that, by comparison with other

    and more successful economies, our banks lend over a shorter term – in

    other words, the money has to be repaid faster. The average term loan is

    now under two years, with a repayment rate of about 65%. This means

    that the annual repayment costs of bank loans for British firms over the life

    of the loan are much higher, the adverse impact on cash-flow is therefore

    more severe, and the need to make an immediate return on investment

    (and a quick boost to profitability) is much greater.

    Annual repayment costs that are several multiples lower than British

    equivalents are a large part of the reason for the greater amount and ease

    of bank borrowing enjoyed by businesses in, for example, Germany and

    Japan, and in the new powerhouses of China, Korea and Taiwan – and that

    is, of course, why they are able to buy up and make a profit from our failing

    assets.

    This is the origin of the much-lamented British disease of short-termism.

    Short-term cash-flow or liquidity is at least as important to British firms as

    longer-term profitability; indeed, it is literally a matter of life and death.

    It is a factor that both inhibits the willingness to borrow (and therefore the

    access to essential investment capital) in the first place, and – if the loan is

    made – greatly increases the chances that it cannot be repaid in accordance

    with the loan period and terms insisted upon by the banks.

    If, as is all too likely, a business borrowing on these terms runs into

    difficulties before the return on the investment funded by the borrowing

    becomes available, the news gets worse. British banks, unlike their

    overseas counterparts, show little interest in the survival of their business

    customers. Their sole concern often appears to be to recover the loan and

    interest payments due to them over the short period specified in the loan

    arrangement. If that means receivership or liquidation – even if the

    business had a good chance of survival were the investment plans funded by

    the loan allowed to proceed – so be it. The banks can congratulate

    themselves not only on the return of the loan and other payments due to

    them sooner than if the business had been allowed to survive but also on

    the money to be made from the disposal of the assets (sometimes to foreign

    buyers) through the receivership process.

    Previous attempts to improve the investment funding of SMEs have failed in

    the United Kingdom, in the face of well-funded bank opposition to any

    changes to improve the existing situation. The current concentration of 84%

    of UK bank savings in six banks and the absence of public local banks of the

    Spakassen type is largely responsible for current failings.

    Bank branches in the UK at present act as facilities for collecting local

    savings and then channelling them almost entirely into London; there is little

    direction of such savings into local SME investments. The

    millions of VAT-paying SMEs in the UK receive virtually no support from

    the branches of the UK banking system except for the standard retail

    service of a money transfer system.

    By contrast, the more successful German economy has seven regional

    banks, 453 Sparkassen (or local savings banks) and a network of 12,600

    branches to provide SME loans from German savings. Each Sparkassen – all

    453 of them – concentrate on providing business loans to SMEs in the area

    where it is located, and each has an interest in, and commitment to,

    ensuring the economic success of its native village, city or region.

    Britain has nothing remotely similar nowadays, but it had such a system

    until the 1880 Bank Amalgamations were put into effect, so destroying

    “country banking” and paving the way for the English Clearing Banks. As Professor

    Glyn Davies said in his 1979 evidence to the Wilson Committee “If Britain

    had had the financial arrangements it has now at the time of the industrial

    revolution, that revolution would have been still-born.”

    This situation is no longer tolerable. If we are to prosper so as to compete

    with powerful overseas competitors, the banking system must be reformed.

    Fresh legislation should be enacted to require British banks to operate

    mainly in just one of four separate categories – as retail banks, mortgage and

    consumer credit banks, merchant banks, and investment credit banks. At the level of the local

    community, community interest credit banks,

    having the function of supporting and developing all of the local SMEs,

    should be created to fulfil that function.

     

    The Creation of Community Interest Credit Banks in Britain

     

    The continuation of the existing banking arrangements, in which the

    merchant bank gambling function is a legally allowable integrated division

    of Clearing Banks with the rest of their banking business, is not a safe way

    forward for the British economy, as Mervyn King has regularly warned us all.

    That was the major cause of the credit crunch, because that structure

    enabled British Banks to gamble with the savings and the circulating credit

    of the UK on the international money, stock and bond markets. The “clever”

    re-packaging of poor quality US housing debt, with the mistaken sale of

    these mortgages as good quality loans when they were not, was the main

    factor in causing the credit crunch.

    The six major UK Clearing Banks give no priority whatsoever to providing long-term capital in

    relatively small amounts to the 4.85 million SMEs of the United Kingdom.

    There is not a single financial organisation in the UK which has the

    objective of collecting financial savings and providing it, as required, at

    local level to those millions of inventive and innovative local SMEs.

    This has been the major conclusion repeatedly found by a number of high-powered

    reports, most recently from the Committee to Review the Functioning of Financial Institutions

    (successfully renamed the “Wilson Committee” by the British Clearing Banks

    so as to imply that report was just a socialist recommendation) which emphasised

    the need for patient, major long-term funding for British industry.

    The industrial revolution was born from the commitment of local and

    “country” banks to the SMEs which then grew into major industries.

    All successful economic developments in all countries – in the UK’s

    industrial revolution, in the USA, in Germany and in Japan – have depended

    not just on the major industries but on the millions of SMEs

    which continually provide the wellspring of small-scale services and

    manufacture without which major national industries could not flourish.

    It is essential that hundreds of local CICs with thousands of branches are

    established throughout the United Kingdom. These local CICs should have a

    “local first” commitment to the success of local SMEs which should be

    provided with the funds required to provide the liquidity, working capital

    and plant and equipment investment to improve their commercial

    operations.

    These local banks could be quickly provided by the nationalisation

    of the Trustee Savings Bank and its local branches, which could be

    regrouped into quasi-independent local-first CICs committed to the success

    of the SMEs and industries in their local area.

     

    © Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015

  • Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 6

    Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government

    By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards

     

    Part 6: The No-Cost Keynesian Stimulation of Demand in the Economy

     

    An incoming Labour government could and should stimulate the economy by

    restoring all the benefits (worth about £20 bn a year) which the Coalition

    Government has reduced or denied to the low-paid, the sick, the disabled,

    the poor and the underprivileged. The case for doing so is based not only on

    social justice and on restoring the integrity of our society but on making

    good the deficiency of demand that has handicapped our economy as a

    consequence of austerity.

    This would be achieved by creating £20 bn of consumer credit at the Bank

    of England to fund the policy during that first year. The costs of that credit

    creation for Government expenditure would be nil and the benefits would

    be immense. If we assume the average UK tax take of about 42%,

    government income would rise by about £8.4 bn; but because much of the

    extra purchasing power might be spent on food and other non-taxed

    necessities, the tax take might be about half of that – say 21%. On the

    other hand, the extra spending would have a multiplier effect of about 2, so

    that the total effect on the UK economy would be a stimulus of about

    £40bn. Even allowing for a lower than average tax take, the Government

    would still gain revenue of £8.4 billion, the economy would receive a

    stimulus of £40 billion (a likely addition to economic growth of about 2.6%)

    and many of the dire effects of the Coalition’s austerity programme would

    be negated. The financial condition of Britain’s poorest would be

    ameliorated; the poor would be more able to afford to eat, heat their

    homes, pay their bills, and live better lives without worrying where the

    next penny was coming from.

    That policy could be continued in the following years but, as the additional

    government taxes came in from economic recovery, the credit required to

    be created would reduce accordingly eventually becoming nil within the

    lifetime of the parliament as economic growth increased due to investment

    credit economics.

     

    The Credit Restoration of the Royal Bank of Scotland

     

    The bad debts of the Bank of Scotland should be immediately purchased in

    their entirety by the Bank of England, using targeted quantitative easing.

    Again, it would cost the Government nothing. The Government would have

    bought assets worth (say) 50% of their book value for nil expenditure. The

    total bad debts of the RBS are estimated at £38 billion, so the Government

    would gain assets of about £19 billion in return for no appreciable cost

    whatsoever. Furthermore, the RBS would cease rejecting loan applications

    from SMEs, where they are urgently needed but where about three out of

    four are currently being turned away. There is no good reason why the RBS

    should continue to do this, when normal business could be resumed

    immediately.

    Through this means, which could be applied to stabilise other British banks

    as necessary, one of the main and continuing consequences of the Global

    Financial Crisis – the overhang of bad debts that inhibit the banks from

    lending – can be negated. Interestingly, one of Richard Werner’s major

    findings from his inquiry into the reasons for the Japanese stagnation over

    recent decades was the inhibiting effect of bad debts on the willingness of

    the Japanese banking system to maintain an adequate level of credit

    creation and therefore of liquidity. In this instance, we have the chance to

    learn from Japanese mistakes. We should be clear that the objection based

    on moral hazard pales into insignificance by comparison with the huge

    economic advantages from pursuing this course.

    Many of those who call themselves economists and many politicians who

    imagine themselves to be competent will be stunned by these proposals, if

    the past is any guide. As Keynes commented, “the difficulty lies not so

    much in developing new ideas as in escaping from the old ones, which

    ramify, for most of us brought up as we have been, into every corner of our

    minds.” And as John Kenneth Galbraith, who was a member of the FDR

    administration when the investment credit creation policy was adopted by

    the US Government, has said, “the creation of money is so simple that the

    mind is repelled.”

    We should remind ourselves that there is nothing new about the creation of

    credit by the Bank of England. No less than £375 bn of credit was created

    to stabilise the liquidity and preserve the operation of British Clearing

    Banks and £80 bn of such credit was created to support Vince Cable’s

    proposal to extend business loans to industry.

    The novel aspect (in British terms at least) of our proposals is that the

    proposed credit is to be focused on useful social and economic objectives –

    on the establishment of more prosperity among the poor and

    disadvantaged, upon the minimal cost fixing of the RBS and other banks and

    upon the creation of the kind of bank support for industry and commerce

    that has existed for centuries in Germany, for about a century in Japan and

    for about a third of a century in China.

     

    The Mechanisms

     

    The primary objective of the incoming Labour Government’s reforms should

    be the establishment of a United Kingdom of abundant capital resources

    and the placement of Britain’s future industries on a sound economic

    footing. Inseparable from that first objective is the reformation of the

    British banking system to ensure its future stability and effectiveness.

    Another objective would be the fulfilment of the Government’s duty of care

    to the people – the relief of the groups disadvantaged by the actions of the

    recent Coalition Government and the restoration of full employment as a

    government objective. Finally, measures should be taken to ensure the

    permanence and continuity of these reforms through major changes in the

    machinery of Government. We set out now our proposals for achieving

    these objectives.

     

    The Re-nationalisation of the Bank of England

     

    The Bank of England should be brought once again under Government

    control. It is unwise for any government to allow any natural monopoly to

    be fully independent, and the control of credit creation is such a central

    aspect of government policy that direct control is required.

    The operating objectives of the Bank of England, as a central departmental

    agency of government policy, will be redefined as the promotion of

    economic growth and the control of inflation within the guidelines of a

    national industrial and social development plan.

    Gordon Brown’s proclamation of the “independence” of the central bank

    was widely applauded at the time and remains a cardinal – and

    unchallenged – element in policy today. Yet handing monetary policy over

    to the tender care of a central bank is simply a reinforcement of the

    current and increasingly discredited orthodoxy that inflation is the only

    concern and proper focus of monetary policy and that its treatment is

    simply a technical matter that is properly the preserve of unaccountable

    bankers, and is not to be trusted to politicians. Quite apart from the

    undemocratic nature of this approach, we have paid a heavy economic

    price for allowing the bankers’ interest to prevail over the interests of the

    economy as a whole.

    It is easy to see why the bankers – and the economists who work for them –

    should support this. It is less easy to see why the politicians should so

    readily have accepted it. Yet the answer is fairly clear. It has suited the

    politicians well to be able to argue that the travails of the economy arise as

    a consequence of inexorable economic forces which must kept in check and

    marshalled by expert technicians. Our governments have thereby been able

    to disclaim any responsibility for policies for which they should be

    ultimately responsible.

    As a matter of interest, this very issue was succinctly discussed by members

    of the Japanese Committee on Financial System Research (Kinyu Seido

    Chosa Kai) as it considered whether to revise the 1942 Japan Law that

    established the Bank of Japan’s primary objective as the promotion of

    economic growth. On that Committee, Dr Shimomura represented the

    Ministry of Finance, while his opposite number was Mr Shigeo Matsumota,

    representing the Bank of Japan.

    Dr Shimomura is reported as having “stressed the inevitable subordination

    of the central bank to the government from two standpoints – that the

    policy of the central bank should be managed and operated in

    full coordination with the general economic policy of the Government and

    that the Government on its part is called upon to hold itself responsible to

    the nation for the outcome of its financial policy.”

    Mr Matsumoto on the other hand “emphasised the necessity of maintaining

    the independence or neutrality of the central bank from the Government on

    the ground that the central bank is first of all assigned with the task of

    contributing to the stabilisation of the currency value….”1‑

    What is clear is that an economic policy that breaks the shackles of current

    orthodoxy would necessarily have to be removed from the exclusive and

    self-interested control of bankers. It would need to be driven by politicians

    who saw the need to ensure that the wider interest is carried into policy

    and is an essential element in setting its direction and gaining for it the

    necessary support.

     

    © Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015

     

    1. From “The Political Economy of Japanese Monetary Policy” by Thomas E Cargill, Michael M Hutchinson and Takatoshi Ito, The MIT Press, Cambridge Massachusetts and London, England, p24.