A Fool’s Paradise?
The pre-election, headline-grabbing, so-called “rock-star economy” may be less in evidence today, but there is still a good deal of self-congratulation about an annual GDP growth-rate of over 3%. There is general agreement that the New Zealand economy is doing pretty well, particularly when compared with what is happening elsewhere.
It is only when we look behind the headline figure that doubts begin to emerge. Unpacking the figures and the trends is an important corrective to unjustified optimism.
First, the current growth rate – a welcome relief from an unnecessarily protracted and slow recovery from recession – owes very little to merits of our own or to the way we have managed our economy. We emerged relatively unscathed from the Global Financial Crisis largely because of the stability of our Australian-owned banks and the buoyancy of our major export markets in Australia and China – both powerful and welcome factors but well beyond our control.
The belated post-GFC stimulus to our economy came from another factor beyond our control and one which on other grounds we could well have done without – the Christchurch earthquake. A government that had set its face against using its powers to get the economy moving again – indeed, that had focused on reducing its own spending so that the economy as a whole was smaller than it need have been – found its hand forced by a natural disaster.
No one doubts that the Christchurch re-build has been a major factor in lifting economic activity, particularly in the construction industry. We would not have had that stimulus to spending, employment and investment if the government had been left to its own devices.
And much of our current optimism rests on a 2014 surge in international commodity prices, particularly for dairy products. Again, we are the beneficiaries but can claim little credit for it, and its effect already seems in any case to have been short-lived.
A fourth factor that has lifted our economy and encouraged a spending spree is the asset inflation in the Auckland housing market, something that is a function of the banks’ willingness to go on creating new credit to lend on house purchase rather than of government policy. Indeed, the government professes itself to be unhappy with what is happening – and the Reserve Bank agrees that it is a problem, not a success.
These factors that underpin and explain our relative success do not in any case come without a price. The increased lending by our banks, for example, simply adds to the billions of dollars in bank profits that are repatriated every year to Australia and that accordingly enlarge the burden on our foreign payments balance.
The consumer spending spree makes inevitable a worsening of our perennial trade deficit, as we suck in more imports to meet our insistence on spending five cents in the dollar more than we earn.
The prices people must now pay for Auckland housing must come from somewhere. They are not matched by any increase in real output and therefore reflect new money created by the banks and placed in the hands of existing home-owners at the expense of those who can’t afford to own their own homes, so that the inequality gap is thereby widened.
The rise in dairy prices throws the spotlight on our increasingly dangerous dependence on a single commodity and on the Chinese market, carrying with it the risk that we are gradually being absorbed into a greater Chinese economy.
But it is when we look to the future that the doubts really begin to grow. The government makes great play of its efforts to reduce its own deficit, without apparently concerning itself at all with the deficit that really matters – that of the country as a whole.
How many of those who are inclined to congratulate the government on its prudence in “reducing the deficit” understand that we continue as a country to live well beyond our means and that the current consumer boom can only make that deficit worse?
How many understand that the government deficit is only a small part of a much wider picture – that of an economy that cannot pay its way – and is in any case virtually inevitable for as long as we have a substantial foreign payments deficit?
How many understand that the current emphasis on high interest rates and an overvalued dollar make it impossible for us to earn enough to pay our way? Or that the price we pay for the continued foreign payments deficit is that we must sell more assets and borrow more as a country to make up the gap – that we are quite literally spending away our future?
Do we understand that, despite all the talk about broadening our economic base, we are more dependent than ever on the price of a single commodity and that our power of self-government is being constantly eroded as we become more dependent on just one customer for that commodity and as more and more of our economy passes in to foreign ownership?
Should we not ask – is New Zealand the paradise we think it to be, or is it becoming a paradise for fools?
Bryan Gould
21 March 2015
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 9
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government
By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards
Part 9 Further Proposals and a Conclusion
The Wage and Salaries Increases Act
One of the main, and perhaps – to western eyes – most surprising features of
Japanese Prime Minister Shinzo Abe’s re-introduction of Shimomuran
economics is his attempt to ensure that there is a rise in Japanese wages.
In marked contrast to Coalition government’s determination to drive down
wages here, he well understands that higher wages are an important way of
raising demand in an economy which is intent on stimulating economic
activity – hence his implication that the advantage of relatively cheap
investment finance will be made available only to those firms that already
pay, or are willing to undertake to pay in the future, a proper level of
wages to their workforce.
An incoming Labour government should take a similar stance, with positive
policies for a greater share of national income by working people. In
particular, there should be an immediate rise in the minimum wage rate to
£8 an hour and an annual incomes and salaries growth target equal to the
estimated rate of inflation plus the estimated rate of growth plus 2% for the
first five years of the Labour Government. This, in the context of the other
policies here proposed, will spread effective purchasing power throughout
the economy and move all families out of poverty within the lifetime of this
government. Zero-hours contracts should be made illegal in the UK. The
disability and unemployment benefits system will so far as possible be uprated
to the levels which would have obtained if the Coalition Government
had never existed.
A second part of wage legislation will be enacted to provide that future
wage and salary increases will be divided, with the increases due to the
estimated annual rate of inflation paid weekly or monthly and the
estimated growth component paid as a lump sum every 1st November. This
measure will ensure the growth of real wages and limit inflation, and
provide earners with lump sum funds, which research has shown are more
likely to be saved, which in turn will increase the emergency funds of
families for holidays or to meet unexpected expenses.
It will also usefully increase the saving of British families, and will, in our restructured financial
system, increase bank funds for industry. That measure has proved very
effective in Japan, where it may have been another policy initiative
originating from the Japanese master economist Osamu Shimomura, and we
think it will be as effective in the UK as it was in Japan.
Improvements in The Machinery of Government
A review of the dominant and self-interested role played in the British
economy by the major banks leaves little room for surprise at the fact that
the various initiatives to support a British economic revival have all failed.
George Brown’s National Enterprise Board, the Industrial Re-Organisation
Corporation, and the more recent suggestion of a National Investment Bank,
all had and have one factor in common – they were inevitably small,
central, initiatives depending upon the co-operation and goodwill of the
Clearing Banks to allow them to work. Not surprisingly, over the last
century and a half, the British Clearing Banks have never had any interest in
permitting the survival of any organisation that could grow to challenge
their virtual monopoly and have ensured that such experiments did not
survive.1
The proposals above for the reform of the banking system will go a
long way towards remedying this situation and allowing genuine reforms to
take effect. If, for any reason, the banks succeed again in frustrating the
flow of lending for investment purposes to industry, it would certainly be
worth looking again at a National Investment Bank which would ensure that
such an objective was met, with that national bank having direct links to
the Local Community Interest Banks.
Finally, there is one additional change
in the machinery of Government that should be put into place.
The Economic Planning Agency
An Economic Planning Agency (EPA) will be set up in the Office of the Prime
Minister to fulfil the following goals:
– to provide competent, timely and accurate advice to the government on
how best to achieve the developing government objectives of increasing
______________________________________________________________
economic growth, managing inflation, and making due provision for the
impact of environmental changes on UK resources
– to report upon the locality and potential of British businesses, particularly
with regard to the development of the UK as a green economy
– to identify and recommend potential and emerging innovations and the
location of key knowledge-based growth hubs in the economy
– to provide a monthly report upon the outcomes of the regional, national
and local investments
– to calculate and comment on, as it may see fit, the capital-output ratios
and other key factors in the economic development of the country
– to identify blockages in the free flow of investment funding for national
and other viable projects, particularly with regard to national sea
defences and the investments required to accelerate the movement into a
greener economy
– to provide an Annual Economic Survey of Britain, summarising the
economic state of the nation and acting to improve the practical
economic understanding of key industries, and
– to report as regularly as it sees fit upon the results of various Government
initiatives and projects, particularly with regard to
– Green energy generation
– The safeguarding of national resources against rising sea levels and
extreme weather events
– The improvement of national education and research and
development facilities and
– Other emerging issues which the EPA wish to bring to the
Government’s attention.
These new institutions will mirror the more competent SME funding
arrangements and other existing industrial funding arrangements in
Germany. These new banks will be guaranteed by government, as in fact all
banks are in the last resort. There can be no foreign objection to the British
Government taking steps to ensure that British domestic industry has access
to financial facilities, similar to those that have existed, and which
continue to exist, to fund foreign industry abroad. Given access to
equivalent funding sources, we are confident that British invention will flow
through to factory floor innovation and British industry will no longer lose
its place in the world and will flourish through the fresh opportunities made
available to it.
Conclusion
It is that fresh economic understanding that should enable an incoming
Labour Government to reshape and reform the future of Britain. The
objective of that Government’s economic policy should be the restoration
of a civilised and progressive Britain where all of its people are free from
want, excellently educated, and achieving their full potential within a
much more prosperous and fairer society. Britain’s place in the world as an
innovative, highly developed manufacturing economy operating at the
leading edge of invention and innovation must be re-built. The fruits of that
success should be more equitably distributed, not only as a matter of social
justice and to secure a more integrated, happier and healthier society, but
also as a stimulus and contributor to continuing economic success.
1 For some of the methods used, see the Henley School of Management
Paper by Peter Scott and Lucy Newton “Jealous monopolists? British banks
and responses to the Macmillan Gap during the 1930s” which is at http://
www.reading.ac.uk/web/FILES/management/036.pdf
© Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 8
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government
By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards
Part 8: The Re-Establishment of British Banks Along Four Main Functional
Lines
As previously remarked, the continuation of the existing banking
arrangements, in which the merchant bank gambling function is integrated
within the rest of the banking business, is – as Mervyn King has regularly warned
– not a safe way for the British economy to proceed. A major re-structuring
of the British Banking sector is required, so that each bank is required to decide
whether its primary function is that of a retail bank, a mortgage and
consumer credit bank, a merchant bank or a local community investment
credit bank.
Retail banks will collect local savings and provide a banking service to local
people and industry, providing the money-handling service which enables
wages and salaries to be paid and all other transactions between buyer and
seller to be carried out. Retail banks will be encouraged, if they wish, to
develop close relationships with local industry (as is the norm in Germany)
and to develop an informed view of the prospects of their local enterprises.
Retail banks with many local branches will be invited to consider becoming
local SME investment credit loan banks as they wish. Local authorities will
be invited to consider setting up Local Authority Banks to help support their
economic development. Government guarantees will be available for the
savings and credit deposits in retail banks of up to £200,000 per individual,
but it is very unlikely such guarantees would ever be required.
Investment credit banks will have the primary purpose of extending long –
term loans at an interest rate of 4% pa over terms of between ten and
twenty years to British-based SMEs. These banks will have the ability to rediscount
their business loans up to the official re-discount limits set under
the “window guidance” at the Bank of England. Such banks will be
completely backed by government. SMEs and other companies taking out
loans and the personnel employed by these companies will be expected to
change their bank so that the loans granted, the wealth created in company
accounts and the wages paid will all initially, and perhaps ultimately, be in
the loan-providing bank. Savings kept in investment credit banks will have a
structured rate of interest so that short-term one-year savings will have an
interest rate of 1% and savings over five years will be offered an interest
rate of inflation plus 1% and thus effectively would be better than inflation-proofed.
Mortgage and consumer credit banks would have the major function of
providing mortgages or consumer credit at relatively low rates of interest.
The mortgage section and consumer credit section of any bank should be
legally operated as a distinct entity within any bank which provides any
other functions. Government guarantees will be available for the savings
and credit deposits in mortgage and retail banks of up to £100,000 per
individual, but again it is very unlikely such guarantees would ever be
required.
Merchant banks will exist as entirely separate free-standing institutions not
associated with any other bank and may attract such savings as may be
commensurate with their level of risk. The risks of complete loss of savings
must be clearly explained to merchant bank savers, and no government
guarantee for any savings placed in a merchant bank will be available.
Merchant banks will be obliged to keep reserves, probably in the range of
10%-20% of total bank assets, commensurate with the gambling risks they
undertake, as determined by the Financial Services Authority.
These measures would go a long way towards constructing a banking system
that provides proper security and guarantees to savers, that truly serves
the public interest and that in particular provides much-needed investment
finance to Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises.
© Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 7
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government
By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards
Part 7: The Community Interest Bank Key to Local SME Development
Despite the provision to the banks of huge sums by way of Quantitative
Easing, very little of that money has found its way into bank lending for
productive investment. The excuses trotted out for this failure include the
age-old claim by British banks that the comparatively low level of their
lending to business does not evidence any reluctance to do so, but merely a
shortage of demand – or, to put it another way, a shortage of suitable
projects on which to lend. But no sense of this can be made unless we
know the terms on which the banks are offering to lend.
And that is precisely, of course, what we are not usually allowed to know.
The banks have traditionally been very coy about the terms they offer. But
the Bank of England has recently required the British Banking system to
make returns showing the extent and the terms of lending to enterprises.
The information that is now available shows that, by comparison with other
and more successful economies, our banks lend over a shorter term – in
other words, the money has to be repaid faster. The average term loan is
now under two years, with a repayment rate of about 65%. This means
that the annual repayment costs of bank loans for British firms over the life
of the loan are much higher, the adverse impact on cash-flow is therefore
more severe, and the need to make an immediate return on investment
(and a quick boost to profitability) is much greater.
Annual repayment costs that are several multiples lower than British
equivalents are a large part of the reason for the greater amount and ease
of bank borrowing enjoyed by businesses in, for example, Germany and
Japan, and in the new powerhouses of China, Korea and Taiwan – and that
is, of course, why they are able to buy up and make a profit from our failing
assets.
This is the origin of the much-lamented British disease of short-termism.
Short-term cash-flow or liquidity is at least as important to British firms as
longer-term profitability; indeed, it is literally a matter of life and death.
It is a factor that both inhibits the willingness to borrow (and therefore the
access to essential investment capital) in the first place, and – if the loan is
made – greatly increases the chances that it cannot be repaid in accordance
with the loan period and terms insisted upon by the banks.
If, as is all too likely, a business borrowing on these terms runs into
difficulties before the return on the investment funded by the borrowing
becomes available, the news gets worse. British banks, unlike their
overseas counterparts, show little interest in the survival of their business
customers. Their sole concern often appears to be to recover the loan and
interest payments due to them over the short period specified in the loan
arrangement. If that means receivership or liquidation – even if the
business had a good chance of survival were the investment plans funded by
the loan allowed to proceed – so be it. The banks can congratulate
themselves not only on the return of the loan and other payments due to
them sooner than if the business had been allowed to survive but also on
the money to be made from the disposal of the assets (sometimes to foreign
buyers) through the receivership process.
Previous attempts to improve the investment funding of SMEs have failed in
the United Kingdom, in the face of well-funded bank opposition to any
changes to improve the existing situation. The current concentration of 84%
of UK bank savings in six banks and the absence of public local banks of the
Spakassen type is largely responsible for current failings.
Bank branches in the UK at present act as facilities for collecting local
savings and then channelling them almost entirely into London; there is little
direction of such savings into local SME investments. The
millions of VAT-paying SMEs in the UK receive virtually no support from
the branches of the UK banking system except for the standard retail
service of a money transfer system.
By contrast, the more successful German economy has seven regional
banks, 453 Sparkassen (or local savings banks) and a network of 12,600
branches to provide SME loans from German savings. Each Sparkassen – all
453 of them – concentrate on providing business loans to SMEs in the area
where it is located, and each has an interest in, and commitment to,
ensuring the economic success of its native village, city or region.
Britain has nothing remotely similar nowadays, but it had such a system
until the 1880 Bank Amalgamations were put into effect, so destroying
“country banking” and paving the way for the English Clearing Banks. As Professor
Glyn Davies said in his 1979 evidence to the Wilson Committee “If Britain
had had the financial arrangements it has now at the time of the industrial
revolution, that revolution would have been still-born.”
This situation is no longer tolerable. If we are to prosper so as to compete
with powerful overseas competitors, the banking system must be reformed.
Fresh legislation should be enacted to require British banks to operate
mainly in just one of four separate categories – as retail banks, mortgage and
consumer credit banks, merchant banks, and investment credit banks. At the level of the local
community, community interest credit banks,
having the function of supporting and developing all of the local SMEs,
should be created to fulfil that function.
The Creation of Community Interest Credit Banks in Britain
The continuation of the existing banking arrangements, in which the
merchant bank gambling function is a legally allowable integrated division
of Clearing Banks with the rest of their banking business, is not a safe way
forward for the British economy, as Mervyn King has regularly warned us all.
That was the major cause of the credit crunch, because that structure
enabled British Banks to gamble with the savings and the circulating credit
of the UK on the international money, stock and bond markets. The “clever”
re-packaging of poor quality US housing debt, with the mistaken sale of
these mortgages as good quality loans when they were not, was the main
factor in causing the credit crunch.
The six major UK Clearing Banks give no priority whatsoever to providing long-term capital in
relatively small amounts to the 4.85 million SMEs of the United Kingdom.
There is not a single financial organisation in the UK which has the
objective of collecting financial savings and providing it, as required, at
local level to those millions of inventive and innovative local SMEs.
This has been the major conclusion repeatedly found by a number of high-powered
reports, most recently from the Committee to Review the Functioning of Financial Institutions
(successfully renamed the “Wilson Committee” by the British Clearing Banks
so as to imply that report was just a socialist recommendation) which emphasised
the need for patient, major long-term funding for British industry.
The industrial revolution was born from the commitment of local and
“country” banks to the SMEs which then grew into major industries.
All successful economic developments in all countries – in the UK’s
industrial revolution, in the USA, in Germany and in Japan – have depended
not just on the major industries but on the millions of SMEs
which continually provide the wellspring of small-scale services and
manufacture without which major national industries could not flourish.
It is essential that hundreds of local CICs with thousands of branches are
established throughout the United Kingdom. These local CICs should have a
“local first” commitment to the success of local SMEs which should be
provided with the funds required to provide the liquidity, working capital
and plant and equipment investment to improve their commercial
operations.
These local banks could be quickly provided by the nationalisation
of the Trustee Savings Bank and its local branches, which could be
regrouped into quasi-independent local-first CICs committed to the success
of the SMEs and industries in their local area.
© Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 6
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government
By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards
Part 6: The No-Cost Keynesian Stimulation of Demand in the Economy
An incoming Labour government could and should stimulate the economy by
restoring all the benefits (worth about £20 bn a year) which the Coalition
Government has reduced or denied to the low-paid, the sick, the disabled,
the poor and the underprivileged. The case for doing so is based not only on
social justice and on restoring the integrity of our society but on making
good the deficiency of demand that has handicapped our economy as a
consequence of austerity.
This would be achieved by creating £20 bn of consumer credit at the Bank
of England to fund the policy during that first year. The costs of that credit
creation for Government expenditure would be nil and the benefits would
be immense. If we assume the average UK tax take of about 42%,
government income would rise by about £8.4 bn; but because much of the
extra purchasing power might be spent on food and other non-taxed
necessities, the tax take might be about half of that – say 21%. On the
other hand, the extra spending would have a multiplier effect of about 2, so
that the total effect on the UK economy would be a stimulus of about
£40bn. Even allowing for a lower than average tax take, the Government
would still gain revenue of £8.4 billion, the economy would receive a
stimulus of £40 billion (a likely addition to economic growth of about 2.6%)
and many of the dire effects of the Coalition’s austerity programme would
be negated. The financial condition of Britain’s poorest would be
ameliorated; the poor would be more able to afford to eat, heat their
homes, pay their bills, and live better lives without worrying where the
next penny was coming from.
That policy could be continued in the following years but, as the additional
government taxes came in from economic recovery, the credit required to
be created would reduce accordingly eventually becoming nil within the
lifetime of the parliament as economic growth increased due to investment
credit economics.
The Credit Restoration of the Royal Bank of Scotland
The bad debts of the Bank of Scotland should be immediately purchased in
their entirety by the Bank of England, using targeted quantitative easing.
Again, it would cost the Government nothing. The Government would have
bought assets worth (say) 50% of their book value for nil expenditure. The
total bad debts of the RBS are estimated at £38 billion, so the Government
would gain assets of about £19 billion in return for no appreciable cost
whatsoever. Furthermore, the RBS would cease rejecting loan applications
from SMEs, where they are urgently needed but where about three out of
four are currently being turned away. There is no good reason why the RBS
should continue to do this, when normal business could be resumed
immediately.
Through this means, which could be applied to stabilise other British banks
as necessary, one of the main and continuing consequences of the Global
Financial Crisis – the overhang of bad debts that inhibit the banks from
lending – can be negated. Interestingly, one of Richard Werner’s major
findings from his inquiry into the reasons for the Japanese stagnation over
recent decades was the inhibiting effect of bad debts on the willingness of
the Japanese banking system to maintain an adequate level of credit
creation and therefore of liquidity. In this instance, we have the chance to
learn from Japanese mistakes. We should be clear that the objection based
on moral hazard pales into insignificance by comparison with the huge
economic advantages from pursuing this course.
Many of those who call themselves economists and many politicians who
imagine themselves to be competent will be stunned by these proposals, if
the past is any guide. As Keynes commented, “the difficulty lies not so
much in developing new ideas as in escaping from the old ones, which
ramify, for most of us brought up as we have been, into every corner of our
minds.” And as John Kenneth Galbraith, who was a member of the FDR
administration when the investment credit creation policy was adopted by
the US Government, has said, “the creation of money is so simple that the
mind is repelled.”
We should remind ourselves that there is nothing new about the creation of
credit by the Bank of England. No less than £375 bn of credit was created
to stabilise the liquidity and preserve the operation of British Clearing
Banks and £80 bn of such credit was created to support Vince Cable’s
proposal to extend business loans to industry.
The novel aspect (in British terms at least) of our proposals is that the
proposed credit is to be focused on useful social and economic objectives –
on the establishment of more prosperity among the poor and
disadvantaged, upon the minimal cost fixing of the RBS and other banks and
upon the creation of the kind of bank support for industry and commerce
that has existed for centuries in Germany, for about a century in Japan and
for about a third of a century in China.
The Mechanisms
The primary objective of the incoming Labour Government’s reforms should
be the establishment of a United Kingdom of abundant capital resources
and the placement of Britain’s future industries on a sound economic
footing. Inseparable from that first objective is the reformation of the
British banking system to ensure its future stability and effectiveness.
Another objective would be the fulfilment of the Government’s duty of care
to the people – the relief of the groups disadvantaged by the actions of the
recent Coalition Government and the restoration of full employment as a
government objective. Finally, measures should be taken to ensure the
permanence and continuity of these reforms through major changes in the
machinery of Government. We set out now our proposals for achieving
these objectives.
The Re-nationalisation of the Bank of England
The Bank of England should be brought once again under Government
control. It is unwise for any government to allow any natural monopoly to
be fully independent, and the control of credit creation is such a central
aspect of government policy that direct control is required.
The operating objectives of the Bank of England, as a central departmental
agency of government policy, will be redefined as the promotion of
economic growth and the control of inflation within the guidelines of a
national industrial and social development plan.
Gordon Brown’s proclamation of the “independence” of the central bank
was widely applauded at the time and remains a cardinal – and
unchallenged – element in policy today. Yet handing monetary policy over
to the tender care of a central bank is simply a reinforcement of the
current and increasingly discredited orthodoxy that inflation is the only
concern and proper focus of monetary policy and that its treatment is
simply a technical matter that is properly the preserve of unaccountable
bankers, and is not to be trusted to politicians. Quite apart from the
undemocratic nature of this approach, we have paid a heavy economic
price for allowing the bankers’ interest to prevail over the interests of the
economy as a whole.
It is easy to see why the bankers – and the economists who work for them –
should support this. It is less easy to see why the politicians should so
readily have accepted it. Yet the answer is fairly clear. It has suited the
politicians well to be able to argue that the travails of the economy arise as
a consequence of inexorable economic forces which must kept in check and
marshalled by expert technicians. Our governments have thereby been able
to disclaim any responsibility for policies for which they should be
ultimately responsible.
As a matter of interest, this very issue was succinctly discussed by members
of the Japanese Committee on Financial System Research (Kinyu Seido
Chosa Kai) as it considered whether to revise the 1942 Japan Law that
established the Bank of Japan’s primary objective as the promotion of
economic growth. On that Committee, Dr Shimomura represented the
Ministry of Finance, while his opposite number was Mr Shigeo Matsumota,
representing the Bank of Japan.
Dr Shimomura is reported as having “stressed the inevitable subordination
of the central bank to the government from two standpoints – that the
policy of the central bank should be managed and operated in
full coordination with the general economic policy of the Government and
that the Government on its part is called upon to hold itself responsible to
the nation for the outcome of its financial policy.”
Mr Matsumoto on the other hand “emphasised the necessity of maintaining
the independence or neutrality of the central bank from the Government on
the ground that the central bank is first of all assigned with the task of
contributing to the stabilisation of the currency value….”1‑
What is clear is that an economic policy that breaks the shackles of current
orthodoxy would necessarily have to be removed from the exclusive and
self-interested control of bankers. It would need to be driven by politicians
who saw the need to ensure that the wider interest is carried into policy
and is an essential element in setting its direction and gaining for it the
necessary support.
© Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015
- From “The Political Economy of Japanese Monetary Policy” by Thomas E Cargill, Michael M Hutchinson and Takatoshi Ito, The MIT Press, Cambridge Massachusetts and London, England, p24.