Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 5
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government
By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards
Part 5 of 9 – The Two Great Traditions in Western Economic Thinking
In studying what actually happened to the Japanese economy and then testing various explanations
for consistency with the observed data, Professor Richard Werner of
Southampton University has placed himself firmly in the first of the two great traditions in
Western economic thought. That first tradition, dating from the time of
Adam Smith, derives economic conclusions from detailed observation and
inductive reasoning based upon the observed facts and data analysis. The
second tradition, most highly developed in the 20th century with the
development of mathematical economic models and more lately computers,
develops a body of deductive reasoning based upon stated theoretical
propositions.
The “bottom up” tradition of observing what is happening, building
economic understanding on the foundation of the observed circumstances
or measured data, and arguing from the observations or the data to the
economic theory is exemplified by Adam Smith’s, The Wealth of Nations.
An example of his technique is his reference to the productive power of
specialisation, which he illustrates by referring to the workers in a pin
factory, and demonstrating how, by breaking down the elements of
production into their constituent parts, a few specialised workers can
create thousands of pins a day when one man could hardly produce one pin
per day on his own. Smith’s book is a major illustration of the major
scientific principle – revived in the Renaissance – of learning by observation,
extracting the particular principle from the general, and basing theory upon
precise, real-world, observation.
The one common factor in the work of Adam Smith, and of John Maynard
Keynes, Osamu Shimomura, Kenneth Kurihara and Richard Werner is that
they all belong to the first tradition in economics, the derivation of valid
theory from detailed observation. Smith in the pin factory; Keynes in his
observation that labour markets, left to market forces, do not produce full
employment; Shimomura deriving the economic model for Japan from his
observation of the productive force of credit creation in the USA from
1938-44; the Japanese-American Kurihara – examining and discussing the
Japanese economic miracle in close-up while acting as the Fulbright
Professor to Tokyo University in 1965; the German-born and Japanese-fluent
Werner in Tokyo, working from the Bank of Japan financial data about
credit creation in Japan, and analysing it into its three key functions of
investment credit, financial credit and the presence (or lack of)
consumption credit, and then proving the predictive linkages using Granger
causative analysis – the work of all these economists is located in the great
inductive tradition of economics.
The second and more recent tradition in Western economics is the “topdown”
approach. This starts from explicitly stated but theoretical
assumptions and then proceeds logically from these to policy
recommendations, using deductive reasoning and highly developed
mathematics. A number of assumptions are made – that consumers and
investors act within perfect markets, with access to perfect information, in
a world in which perfect information has levelled out local differences. On
this basis, deductive logic arrives at economic models which appear to have
great logical validity but which – as Keynes asserted – may bear little
relation to reality. In view of the imperfect outcomes of this second
approach, as evidenced by the declining fortunes of many western
economies, there is much to be said for a return to the methods used by
Adam Smith and his great successors.
Three Practical Illustrations of the Use of Credit Creation
As we have seen, if credit creation is left to the tender mercies of self-interested
commercial banks, credit will be largely devoted to gambling on
property creating a housing and other asset bubbles so as to maximize
profits for private shareholders while the real economy languishes for want
of adequate liquidity and investment capital, and the economy as a whole is
handicapped by a shortfall in effective demand.
An incoming Labour government, however, fully understanding the use of
credit creation in the public interest, could resolve many outstanding
problems. We provide three examples of the way in which this would work
to achieve quite different kinds of objectives.
The Acceleration of British Economic Growth Through Higher Investment
This aspect of central bank credit creation is by far the most potent policy
within a government’s control. It would allow the government to create
earmarked investment credits, cost-free, for use by SMEs and other private
companies to ensure the fulfilment of the Government’s economic, social
and environmental policies.
The provision of these funds would be directed by the Bank of England,
reflecting advice from the Treasury – a technique described as “Window
Guidance” when used by the Bank of Japan in using similar mechanisms in
the 1960s and 1970s. There would need to be a bank which was, or ideally a
number of banks which were, prepared to use its local branches as taps for
local investment (as the Sparkassen in Germany are) and not just – as
currently occurs – as drains to collect local saving, taking it away for
whatever fashionable policy use the London HQ decides.
The initial creation of credit could be at the level of about 10% of GDP, that
is about £150 bn a year; multiplier effects might create an eventual new
level of commercial and industrial funding of about £300 billion. We would
expect these funds to be initially used to provide an improvement of about
£100 billion in business liquidity, about £100 billion in early new plant and
equipment investment and about £100 billion in funding higher levels of raw
materials, working capital and work in progress. If the usual level of tax
take of 42% applies to the new investment and to work in progress,
government revenue receipts could increase by about £84 billion – an
excellent return to government in addition to the overall benefit to the
economy as a whole. Furthermore, that new investment would produce a
permanent increase in output of about an extra £100 billion a year, equal to
a permanent increase in GDP of about 6.7%, and a permanent rise in
government revenue of about £42 billion a year. We think these changes
would occur within about two years.
Some economists have traditionally argued that, because an extra job in
manufacturing industry has historically created another job in the service
industries, the final effect could be twice the initial stimulus. It is indeed
likely that placing the economy on a higher growth path will enable the
under-performing assets and spare capacity in our industries to respond to
the higher levels of demand created by this stimulus.
The experience of other countries shows that investment credit economics
works by creating wealth in the productive sector of the economy. The
loans made are almost completely repaid (the failure rate is typically about
2.5%) out of the growth of the economy resulting from the additional
investment. The failure rate of these loans matters little in any case
because the loans cost nothing to create; their consequences matter,
however, because they produce their targeted effect in reducing poverty,
stabilising the banking system, and creating widespread prosperity through
many flourishing private industries in all the areas of the country.
The increase in output would obviously negate the risk that a substantial
increase in the money supply could be inflationary, as Keynes recognized
and as the Japanese experience in particular demonstrates. The
consequence of the increased money supply could well be a fall in the
international value of the pound, which could only be helpful in
ameliorating the competitiveness problem of British industry and in
ensuring readily available markets for increased British production.
Unemployment will fall to a low level. Social security payments will
automatically reduce as fuller employment becomes the norm and
Government income will cease to be disappointing, ending the need for
austerity in government expenditure and bringing to an end all of its ill
effects for our people.
© Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 4
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government
By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards
Part 4 of 9 – Shimomuran Economics
The body of developed policy that underpins Asian industrial and economic
success is not understood in the West, yet it was clearly foreshadowed in
the work of the greatest western economist of the twentieth century, John
Maynard Keynes. It is a sad reflection on western economists that the
Keynesian insights were most fully developed by the great Japanese
economist, Dr Osama Shimomura 1910-89, whose work has only recently
come to the attention of western economists by virtue of the sustained
efforts over four decades by the second author of this paper.
An indication of the extent to which Shimomura has been overlooked in the
West is the fact that his works have never been translated Into English
except by the Indian Statistical Institute1, (and even in that work the
Development Bank of Japan has edited out Shimomura’s key formulae).
Shimomura enjoys, however, a towering reputation in his own country. The
Development Bank of Japan offers a “Shimomura Fellowship” to
commemorate his life on the basis that “during his long career as an
economic scholar and critic, Dr Shimomura rose to become Japan’s most
influential post-war economist, founding a school of thought based on the
“Shimomura Theory,” which attracted numerous followers.”2
He was acknowledged, within Japan and during his lifetime, as the “brains
behind the Japanese economic miracle” – the most successful national
economic growth plan of the 20th century. Five of his published works
became available in the British Library last year but there seems to be little
interest in how Japan, in the course of a few decades, progressed from the
war-damaged, impoverished country of 1945 to become one of the most
highly developed and powerful industrial economies in the world.
Shimomura’s major contribution to macro-economics is his economic growth
model, the basis of which was that the total level of Japanese investment is
equal to the natural investment level (that is, investment financed by
savings) plus the additional investment financed by credit creation
originating at the Bank of Japan. The model illustrated the range of that
additional credit-created investment as no less than 10% to 15% of national
income a year.
It is generally agreed by most economists, following Keynes, that
investment is the major key to economic development and growth.
Shimomura’s economic model applied an extension of the Keynesian
analysis and showed that an economy could selectively increase its
investment level through an increase in investment credit at the central
bank, if that credit was earmarked for commercial and industrial
investment. The rapidity of Japanese industrial development in the 1960s
and 1970s, in apparent response to the stimulus provided by investment
credit-creation by the Bank of Japan under instructions from the
government, is widely seen in Asian economies as a vindication of
Shimomuran policies.
Professor Kenneth K Kurihara (1910-1972) – the Distinguished Professor of
Economic Theory at the State University of New York in Binghampton,
teacher of macro-economics at Princeton and Rutgers, the State University
of New Jersey, guest lecturer at the universities of Oxford and Cambridge,
and author of “The Growth Potential of the Japanese Economy” – was one
of the most influential interpreters of Shimomuran economics; he also had
the great advantage of being able to write in English. He concluded that
“if, therefore, greater investment can be financed partly by credits, there
is no need for that ‘abstinence’ which the classical economists considered
necessary for economic progress, any more than there is for that ‘austerity’
which some present day underdeveloped countries impose on already
under-consuming populations at the constant peril of social unrest. Nor is it
difficult, in such credit-creating circumstances, to agree with Keynes’
observation that investment and consumption should be regarded as
complementary rather than competitive.”3
After more than two decades of persistent stagnation, during which
Shimomuran policies were lost sight of, and supplanted by policies urged on
the Japanese by the IMF and western economists, Shimomura is now back in
favour in Japan. The Prime Minister of Japan, Shinzo Abe, announced on 19
April 2013 in a speech to the Japan National Press Club that Japan is once
again implementing Shimomuran economics – he explicitly made two
references to Dr Shimomura – in order to end the Japanese depression and
restore high growth to create once again what he described as “a Japan of
abundant capital.”4
Western economists, however, seem to be unaware of this revival of
Shimomuran economics. On the rare occasions that they have been invited
to consider the issue, they have maintained that correlation is not
causation, and that there is no evidence that the new credit created by the
Bank of Japan “caused” the observed growth in the 1960s and 1970s, or
that the cessation of that growth was the consequence of abandoning credit
creation. And there the argument might have rested except for two recent
developments.
First, the British economist Sir Clive Granger produced, in a 1969 paper in
Econometrica, a new statistical technique called Granger Predictive
Causation Analysis – an achievement that led in 2003 to his award, along
with his colleague Robert Engle, of a Nobel Prize for contributions to
economics. The Granger Causality Analysis tests the validity of predictive
causative links between two economic factors; using Granger predictive
analysis, it can be shown whether there is a predictive link between two
items of economic time series.
Second, and more recently, detailed and expert work on the course of the
Japanese economy – both its period of sustained and almost unprecedented
growth, and its subsequent period of stubborn stagnation – was undertaken
by Professor Richard Werner, professor of economics at the University of
Southampton. Professor Werner originated the term “quantitative easing”
and in 1991 predicted the imminent ‘collapse’ of the Japanese banking
system and the threat of the “greatest recession since the Great
Depression”. He is a specialist in the Japanese economy and became the
first Shimomura Fellow at the Research Institute for Capital Formation at
the Development Bank of Japan where he spent ten years in the 1990s.
Professor Werner has applied Granger Predictive Causation Analysis to the
Japanese data over a long period and has shown in his book “New Paradigm
in Macroeconomics” – that there is a clear Granger causation predictive link
between investment credit creation at the Bank of Japan and subsequent
rates of Japanese economic growth, both positive and negative. He also
found that the causative link that is so clear in the case of investment
credit creation does not hold good in respect of any other of the
candidates, such as interest rates, structural changes, and so on, that are
often advanced as potential explanations for the vagaries of the Japanese
economy over five decades. Significantly, Werner also found that excessive
credit creation where that credit is not earmarked for use in new
investment in productive capacity will finds its outlet in speculation and the
creation of asset bubbles, as occurred in Japan from 1986-91.
Werner’s use of the Granger technique and the conclusions he is able to
draw allow us to say with certainty that the use of investment credit
creation has been the essential element in determining the rate of growth
for the Japanese economy. Empirical observation and the analysis of the
observed data allow for no other explanation. It is on that basis that we can
extrapolate from the Japanese experience, as identified by Werner, to
western economies, and say that – since advanced economies function very
similarly, whether in Japan or elsewhere – the solution to the poor
performance and lagging development of western economies is the adoption
of investment credit economics, which is fully capable of reversing the ill effects,
including the damage to personal incomes and the social fabric, of
austerity.
1 A reference to that inadequate translation of what is perhaps Shimomura’s most significant
books, Seicho Seisaku No Kihon Mondai (Basic Problems in Growth Policy, 1961) can be found
http://books.google.co.uk/books/about/Basic_Problems_of_Economic_Growth_Policy.html?
id=DyNjHQAACAAJ&redir_esc=y
2 See http://www.dbj.jp/ricf/en/fellowship/
3 See “The Growth Potential of the Japanese Economy” (John Hopkins Press Maryland 1971), pp.
137-138
4 http://www.kantei.go.jp/foreign/96_abe/statement/201304/19speech_e.html
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 3
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government
By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards
Part 3 of 9 – The Different Uses of Credit Creation
Credit creation when properly deployed can serve five main purposes, each
having major and differential effects on the real economy. We cannot
expect, and nor can an incoming Labour government, to produce better
economic outcomes unless we understand the differences between them.
First, credit creation may be undertaken (and usually is) for purely
speculative purposes. Its principal purpose and effect is to fund housing
purchase and speculative financial transactions; it is often the main factor
in the development of housing, land and asset bubbles. It is this aspect of
credit creation that attracts most attention in today’s economy and which is
the main focus of the banks’ activities, since it is the easiest business to
attract, the most secure (since mortgages guarantee the value of the credit
in most cases) and the most profitable.
It is also the principal factor in stimulating inflation; housing values, in
particular, rise sharply as large volumes of credit-created money flow into
the housing market, and the consequent asset inflation is inevitably
followed by consumer led inflation as home-owners use the increased value
of their equity to increase consumption. This is, of course, of great
significance, given that the control of inflation is the prime and virtually
only focus of macro-economic policy; it suggests that the use of interest
rates to tighten monetary conditions, impacting as it does on the whole
economy, fails to address effectively and accurately the real cause of
inflationary pressures and is an unnecessarily broad and badly focused
instrument that does great damage to the wider economy at the same time.
The overwhelming dominance of credit creation for speculative purposes –
for both housing and other financial transactions – has other adverse
features. It distorts the desired operation of the economy by diverting
investment capital away from productive purposes, and by creating asset
bubbles in both residential housing and financial assets, not least in western
stock exchanges; and the resultant constant inflationary impetus then has
to be restrained by measures such as higher interest rates, so that the
chances of greater innovation and productivity are further prejudiced.
Despite all of these downsides, credit creation for speculative purposes as a
major economic factor impacting on the real economy is virtually ignored
by our policy-makers, except to the extent that it is seen as perfectly
normal and relatively benign.
The second kind of credit creation operates as an important element in
demand management. It is used to raise purchasing power by putting more
money in people’s pockets, and thereby can help to resolve the problem of
deficient demand that Keynes identified as the key element in the Great
Depression and that continues to characterise recessionary conditions today.
It would normally be undertaken by the banks, under direction from the
central bank or the Treasury, though it could also be undertaken directly by
the central bank or the government. It is little used in today’s Britain, not
surprisingly, when the Coalition government does not recognise a deficiency
of demand as the feature of a recessionary situation that needs correction.
It has, however, returned to favour as a counter-recessionary instrument in
the thinking of some of our leading monetary economists. Keynes had
suggested in the 1930s – half-jokingly but so as to make a serious point –
that a valuable counter-recessionary outcome could be obtained by burying
money in the ground and then paying firms to employ people to dig it up.
Their increased income would represent a significant increase in purchasing
power and therefore demand.
Such a policy today is often pejoratively characterised as “helicopter
money” – the notion that demand could be raised if pound notes were
scattered from the air – but has been seriously analysed by economists such
as Adair Turner and Michael Woodford who have reached the point of
debating whether it would best be delivered by fiscal measures (such as tax
cuts) or by monetary policy (essentially printing money).1
Credit creation undertaken to raise demand does not mean that it cannot
serve other purposes at the same time; or, to put it in another way, credit
creation undertake for other purposes, such as funding the purchase of
assets or providing capital for investment, may well also have the additional
effect of lifting the level of demand. As we shall see, the crucial question
is then as to whether the increased demand is merely inflationary or is
matched by increased output.
Thirdly, credit creation can also be undertaken for the purpose of stabilising
the financial system; this technique, which has been called Quantitative
Easing over recent times, has been implemented by governments in both
the UK and the US, and was meant to remedy – in the wake of the Global
Financial Crisis – the precarious situation of an otherwise bankrupt financial
system. In the case of the UK, the policy took the form of the Bank of
England’s £375bn of financial credit to stabilise the UK Clearing Banks but it
did nothing to benefit the wider economy. The greater proportion of that
sum was used by the banks to strengthen their balance sheets (and to
resume paying large bonuses); very little found its way into lending to the
Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises that desperately needed help in
maintaining adequate liquidity (and for plant and equipment investment).
Credit creation for the purpose of funding major innovative programmes –
sometimes called Government Credit Creation (GCC) – is the fourth kind of
credit creation and is designed to enable major innovative structural
economic change, such as the invention of the atomic bomb, the mass production
of synthetic rubber in the US in 1940-44, and President Obama’s
Energy Initiative; it is often resorted to in wartime. The intention is to
stimulate innovation in the public sector or infrastructure area of the
economy and to undertake large-scale projects that are vitally important to
the economy but are too large or not commercially rewarding enough to
attract private capital.
This kind of credit creation for public purpose is being supplanted
increasingly in Britain today by Public/Private Partnerships, on the specious
ground that they offer better value to the taxpayer; the reality is that they
are much more expensive than publicly funded projects, but they have the
great merit in the eyes of right-wing governments of offering fat profits to
their friends in private industry.
The fifth and, for our purposes, most interesting and important form of
credit creation is usually called Investment Credit Creation (ICC). This form
of credit is targeted at increasing investment in the plant and equipment
level in private industry, with the goal of encouraging productivity
improvement, accelerating the rate of economic growth and providing full
employment. Investment Credit Creation is usually delivered through the
local banks (if you have any) at the behest of the central bank and the
government. It is this aspect of credit creation that has been virtually
ignored in western economies over recent decades but which offers by far
the best prospect of breaking out of our seemingly irreversible economic
decline.
There is today virtually no understanding in Britain and other western
countries of how Investment Credit Creation functions and of the benefits it
can bring to economic development. The provision of credit – that is, bank
lending – is seen almost exclusively in terms of its capacity to stimulate
inflation and is seen therefore as a potential threat rather than as an
essential element in producing a better economic performance.
This is notwithstanding Keynes’ perceptive assertion that there is no reason
why the provision of credit for the purpose of productive investment should
not precede the increase in output that it is intended to produce, provided
that the increase occurs over an appropriate time frame. Other economies
have understood and benefited from this insight and have used Investment
Credit Creation to stimulate growth, without being inhibited by the
conviction that any increase in the money supply must necessarily be
inflationary.
There are, in fact, many persuasive instances from both recent history and
from other countries of the successful deployment of Investment Credit
Creation. One of the most striking examples of the use of credit creation,
not to inflate the property market for private profit as is done in the West
at present, but to stimulate rapid industrial growth, was provided by the
United States at the outbreak of the Second World War, when Roosevelt
used the two years before Pearl Harbour to provide virtually unlimited
capital to American industry – simply by printing money – so that the
country could rapidly increase its military capability.
Roosevelt encountered the usual objections from conventional economists
but the exigencies of war and his own political strength and will prevailed.
The results were spectacular and hugely significant. American industrial
output grew on average by an unprecedented 12.2% per annum from 1938
to 1944 – an outcome that went a long way towards enabling the US, and
the Allies more generally, to win the Second World War.
An equally impressive instance is provided by Japan in the 1960s and 1970s,
when Japanese industry was enabled by similar means to grow at a rapid
rate so as to dominate the world market for mass-produced manufactured
goods. Western economists have typically shown no interest in how this was
done and are almost totally ignorant of the work of leading growth expert
economists such as the Japanese Osamu Shimomura and the American-
Japanese Kenneth Kurihara. We shall look in more detail 2 later at exactly
how Investment Credit Creation was specifically implemented by the Bank
of Japan, at the behest of the government and following the advice of
Shimomura and his colleagues, and accordingly brought about the Japanese
economic miracle.
More recently, China has used similar techniques to finance the rapid
expansion of Chinese manufacturing. The Chinese central bank, and their
provincial counterparts, under instructions from the government, makes
credit available to Chinese enterprises that can demonstrate their ability to
comply with the government’s economic priorities. Enterprises that wish to
build or buy new capacity in compliance with the overall industrial strategy
are provided with the required investment capital, obtained through cost-free
credit creation; Chinese manufacturing capacity in particular has
largely been funded by such government-authorised new credit, as has the
huge purchasing programme of strategic assets from around the world that
is currently being undertaken by Chinese enterprises. This is admittedly, in
principle at least, easier to bring about in a totalitarian regime than in the
UK, but in practice there is nothing to stop a British government from
requiring the central bank, as the Chinese have done, to create cost-free
credit for specific (and productive) purposes.
Other Asian countries, such as Korea and Taiwan, have applied similar
policies in order to produce rapid industrial growth. Typically, however,
Western economists have arrogantly assumed that these successful
economies have nothing to teach us, and are easily dismissed as
undeveloped economies relying for competitive advantage on cheap labour;
the reality is, of course, that these economies are, as a consequence of the
rapid economic growth and industrial development made possible by
Investment Credit Creation, delivering incomes and living standards to their
populations that are approaching and in some cases surpassing those in the
West.
1 See www.voxeu.org/article/helicopter-money-policy-option
© Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 2
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government
By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards
Part 2 of 9: Stimulating Wealth Creation
If we are to find that better way, we must clearly understand the failures
and deficiencies of what has gone before. A major milestone in that quest
for understanding was reached earlier this year when the Bank of England,
in an article published in its first quarterly bulletin for the year1 became
the first significant central bank to acknowledge that the vast proportion of
money in our economy (calculated by the authors at 97% of the total money
supply) is created by the banks. This admission, which has been hotly
contested and denied by bankers and economists for decades, if not
centuries, casts a whole new light on the meaning of money and its
significance for economic policy, and is the key to a new approach – not
only as a response to recession – but as the foundation of a successful
economic policy.
We need not explore here the mechanisms by which the banks create
credit; suffice to say that they are well set out in the Bank of England
paper, and in the end amount to the simple fact that the banks are not
simply intermediaries, bringing savers and lenders together. They do not
lend money deposited with them but instead lend money that they
themselves create by making book entries unsupported by anything other
than their willingness to lend. But while the mechanisms may be simple,
the implications for policy are huge.
The facts that the quantity of money is almost entirely a function of bank
policy and that its continuing but regulated growth is the normal and
required condition for a well-functioning economy suggest strongly that the
conventional treatment of money as a neutral factor in economic policy is
completely mistaken. Current monetarist orthodoxy treats the money
supply as reflecting more or less automatically the needs of the real
economy, and impacting on it only in the sense that, if it is allowed to grow
too fast, it will generate inflation. The reality is, however, that the rate of
growth in the money supply is not just a function of the level of real
economic activity but is, as we shall see and according to the purposes to
which it is put, an important determinant of that level.
It is worth registering at this point that the banks’ remarkable monopoly
power to create (or “print”) money is exercised entirely in the interests of
profits for their own shareholders rather than of the economy as a whole.
It might be thought that this private exploitation of such an important
power would warrant the most careful public scrutiny, yet it attracts
virtually no attention from policymakers, other than in terms of countering
inflation; the Coalition government prefers to focus on reducing
government spending, as the supposedly essential feature of macroeconomic
policy.
They thereby totally overlook the fact that it is extraordinarily important
for the purposes of economic policy-making as a whole to understand the
impact of private money-creation on this scale and, in particular, to analyse
the purposes for which that credit is created.
A Labour government should no longer, in other words, accept that credit
creation by the banks is benign, and automatically serves – because it is
allegedly self-regulating – the public interest; a more effective economic
policy depends crucially on an acknowledgment that credit creation (and
therefore the whole of monetary policy) is hugely important and impacts
directly and substantially on the development of the real economy, and can
be made to serve a variety of wider economic interests rather than simply
those of private profit-seeking bank shareholders. A Labour government
that took this position would surely be encouraged to find that, on this
issue, public opinion had got there first.
Keynes was well aware of the fact, and of the almost unlimited potential,
of credit creation by the banks and recognised it as an important element in
macroeconomic policy. His pre-war contention that “there are no intrinsic
reasons for the scarcity of capital” is supported by compelling evidence, not
least now by the Bank of England’s recognition that money is created by the
banks from nothing. What should now be fully recognised, however, is that
the purposes of credit creation could and should extend well beyond the
funding of house purchase, which is currently its major feature.
Credit creation at the central bank, if properly directed and managed, can
be used to selectively increase the private investment level of the country,
as has previously occurred in all very high-growth economies, and as could
happen in Britain.
1Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, 2014, Q1 “Money Creation in the Modern Economy” by
Michael McLeay, Amar Radia and Ryland Thomas of the Bank’s Monetary Analysis Directorate.
© Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 1
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government
By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards
Part 1 of 9: The Coalition Government’s Failed Austerity Programme
The outcome of the next general election cannot be confidently predicted but one thing is clear; the odds on both a Labour election victory and a successful term in office would be greatly increased if the Labour leadership had the confidence and courage to develop and deliver a convincing alternative economic policy.
At present, Ed Miliband and Ed Balls seem inhibited from attacking the
failed policies of austerity (to which George Osborne claims there is no
alternative) and are content to focus on policy in other areas as a means of avoiding any real debate on economic policy. Yet there is, as both
experience and reason demand, a growing consensus that austerity has
failed and, as a consequence, an urgent need for Labour to describe clearly what an alternative and better policy should be and how it would operate.
The purpose of these articles is to identify one of the basic and central
issues on which that successful alternative policy should be developed. A full understanding and adoption of the proposals advanced here would allow the Labour leadership, in the run-up to the election, to attack the
Coalition’s economic record with greater conviction and confidence, and
would provide the launching-pad in government for a long-delayed and
hence urgently needed restoration of Britain’s economic fortunes.
Not A Moment Too Soon
The new direction that an incoming Labour government must adopt will
come not a moment too soon. The damage done by the Coalition
government is cumulative and fundamental, and extends beyond purely
economic failure to social dislocation and political disintegration.
In economic terms George Osborne’s record is appalling. The so-called
recovery has been delayed unnecessarily for more than half a decade and means that a return to pre-2008 living standards is still many years away.
Median GDP is still 3% below 2007 levels, and since the population has
increased by3%, that means an average fall in individual incomes of 6%.
The decline of the productive sector and particularly of manufacturing has meant that only 10% of our GDP is now accounted for by manufacturing -the lowest proportion of any major developed economy – and our share of world trade has fallen to just 2.7%.
Coalition polices have resulted in the sharpest fall in living standards in
more than 60 years. According to data from the Institute of Fiscal Studies, average wages have fallen by over £1,600 since 2010, at an average rate of over £530 a year. The pre-Coalition reduction in median income (not the same as average wages, but an acceptable proxy), can be calculated at about £5,400 over thirty years (1980 to 2010) – about £180 a year – so that the Coalition has produced a reduction in worker incomes of almost three times the previous trend.
But these figures relate only to the working population, and take no
account of the reduction in unemployment and disability benefits, the
denial of benefits to mothers seeking work because they have not been
employed during the previous two years, and the exclusion from the data
for both the employed and unemployed of the growing practice of zero hours contracts, all of which mean that the real extent of income cuts is
much larger than official figures indicate.
The burden imposed on working people has not of course been shared by the wealthiest people in our society. According to an Oxfam report1, the richest 5 families in Britain have more wealth than the poorest 20% of the population. That level of inequality is unprecedented since records began in the UK.
In an even more recent report2, Oxfam also reports that the Coalition’s
welfare cuts have pushed 1.75 million of the UK’s poorest households
deeper into poverty, suffering an absolute cut in their income in the past
three years and leaving them struggling to cover food and energy bills.
The national scandal that millions of children in the UK are going to bed hungry is not some accidental by-product of Coalition policy. It is the inevitable and deliberate consequence of policies pursued by a government that is “of the privileged, by the privileged, for the privileged”.
The disadvantaged poor – the disabled, the sick and the unemployed – have suffered, through cuts in their benefits, the greatest burdens in dealing with the recession. SCOPE, the charity supporting disabled people, have shown, for example, that 600,000 people in the UK lost a total of £2.62 billion pounds a year from Monday 8 April 2013 as a result of the Coalition Government abolishing the Disability Living Allowance (DLA) and introducing the new Personal Independence Payment (PIP), with tighter eligibility criteria and a controversial new assessment. The purpose of that change is not to improve service or to make things more fair but simply to save money. The lack of concern for the most disadvantaged in our society was compounded by the amazingly (and deliberately) inaccurate statements about incapacity benefit made by Ian Duncan Smith.
Coalition policies have disproportionately affected women, who are
more often found in lower-paid occupations and in the caring
professions. An analysis of Treasury data by House of Commons Library
researchers in 2012 showed that £11.1bn of the £14.9bn raised from the
five spending reviews since 2010 comes from women even though they earn less than men on average. Planned changes to tax credits, child benefits and public sector pensions were largely to blame. They came shortly after the government announced plans to cut the 50p top rate of tax for all those earning over £150,000.
A Failed Banking System
The failures of the Coalition government have extended into other areas of policy. One of the principal reasons for both the excesses that led to the Global Financial Crisis and the difficulty we have had in recovering from recession has been the absence of a responsible and supportive financial-industrial banking system in the United Kingdom. The Coalition Government acknowledged as much in “The Coalition: our programme for government”3 where they promised that, “We will reform the banking system to avoid a repeat of the financial crisis, to promote a competitive economy, to protect and sustain jobs”.
None of this has been done. There has been no reform of the banking
system with the result that, as Mervyn King has regularly warned, a repeat of the financial crisis is still a major risk.
They further promised that “We will introduce a banking levy and seek a
detailed agreement on implementation.” The banking levy was introduced in 2010 and was intended to raise £2.5 bn, but has raised nothing like that sum. In the 2014 Budget, George Osborne restructured the levy to provide maximum limits for individual banks and five bands, which meant a cut that is disproportionally beneficial to the very largest banks.
They also undertook to “bring forward detailed proposals for robust action to tackle unacceptable bonuses in the financial services sector; in
developing these proposals, we will ensure they are effective in reducing
risk.” Less than six months after the Coalition came into Government, the proposal to deal with bonuses was abandoned. Bonuses are back with a vengeance.
A fourth promise to “bring forward detailed proposals to foster diversity in
financial services, promote mutuals and create a more competitive banking industry” produced no action whatsoever, while a fifth to “develop effective proposals to ensure the flow of credit to viable SMEs … which will include consideration of both a major loan guarantee scheme and the use of net lending targets for the nationalised banks” produced an extra £80 bn of re-discounting of loans by banks, part of which may have proved useful to some banks who wished to reduce the bank levy, but which nevertheless produced a fall in loans to SMEs of about £56bn.
The failure to take effective action on any of these issues has been, as we shall see later, hugely detrimental to any attempt to correct one of the main deficiencies in the management of the British economy. The failures were compounded by the fate of the Parliamentary Commission on Banking Standards which was established in July 2012, following the LIBOR-rigging crisis. The Commission’s report was set aside by politicians who showed themselves anxious to find reasons to shy away from the necessary reforms. It was claimed that such reforms had been rendered unnecessary by reforms already being implemented, that they would damage the competitiveness of the City and cost jobs, and that they would harm the banks’ ability to support the rest of the economy.
The UK’s competitiveness will be threatened in the long-term by this
indifference to the dangers associated with poor banking standards and
culture. If the arguments against complacency and inaction have not been heeded now, when the crisis in banking standards has been laid bare, they are yet more certain to be ignored in the future when memories have faded.
It should be understood, however, that the real problem with British
banking is not about dubious ethics but that it does not, unlike foreign
banks, see the funding of investment in productive capacity as its main
function. The right ethics with the wrong agenda is no recipe for British
economic recovery.
The list of failures demonstrates one central theme; because the Coalition Government does not understand the process of wealth creation at all, their focus is on the side-issue of making economies in the budgeted cost of government. Their obsession with the objective of achieving a balanced budget blinds them to the fact that there is a much better way to govern Britain – a way that increases the wealth and welfare of all, as we will illustrate in the following articles in this series.
1 www.theguardian.com/business/2014/mar/17/oxfam-report-scale-britain-growing-financial-inequality?
CMP=EMCNEWEML6619I2
2 www.theguardian.com/politics/2014/apr/22/welfare-cuts-drive-uk-poorest-poverty-oxfam
3 www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/78977/ _programme_for_government.pdf
© Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015