Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 7
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government
By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards
Part 7: The Community Interest Bank Key to Local SME Development
Despite the provision to the banks of huge sums by way of Quantitative
Easing, very little of that money has found its way into bank lending for
productive investment. The excuses trotted out for this failure include the
age-old claim by British banks that the comparatively low level of their
lending to business does not evidence any reluctance to do so, but merely a
shortage of demand – or, to put it another way, a shortage of suitable
projects on which to lend. But no sense of this can be made unless we
know the terms on which the banks are offering to lend.
And that is precisely, of course, what we are not usually allowed to know.
The banks have traditionally been very coy about the terms they offer. But
the Bank of England has recently required the British Banking system to
make returns showing the extent and the terms of lending to enterprises.
The information that is now available shows that, by comparison with other
and more successful economies, our banks lend over a shorter term – in
other words, the money has to be repaid faster. The average term loan is
now under two years, with a repayment rate of about 65%. This means
that the annual repayment costs of bank loans for British firms over the life
of the loan are much higher, the adverse impact on cash-flow is therefore
more severe, and the need to make an immediate return on investment
(and a quick boost to profitability) is much greater.
Annual repayment costs that are several multiples lower than British
equivalents are a large part of the reason for the greater amount and ease
of bank borrowing enjoyed by businesses in, for example, Germany and
Japan, and in the new powerhouses of China, Korea and Taiwan – and that
is, of course, why they are able to buy up and make a profit from our failing
assets.
This is the origin of the much-lamented British disease of short-termism.
Short-term cash-flow or liquidity is at least as important to British firms as
longer-term profitability; indeed, it is literally a matter of life and death.
It is a factor that both inhibits the willingness to borrow (and therefore the
access to essential investment capital) in the first place, and – if the loan is
made – greatly increases the chances that it cannot be repaid in accordance
with the loan period and terms insisted upon by the banks.
If, as is all too likely, a business borrowing on these terms runs into
difficulties before the return on the investment funded by the borrowing
becomes available, the news gets worse. British banks, unlike their
overseas counterparts, show little interest in the survival of their business
customers. Their sole concern often appears to be to recover the loan and
interest payments due to them over the short period specified in the loan
arrangement. If that means receivership or liquidation – even if the
business had a good chance of survival were the investment plans funded by
the loan allowed to proceed – so be it. The banks can congratulate
themselves not only on the return of the loan and other payments due to
them sooner than if the business had been allowed to survive but also on
the money to be made from the disposal of the assets (sometimes to foreign
buyers) through the receivership process.
Previous attempts to improve the investment funding of SMEs have failed in
the United Kingdom, in the face of well-funded bank opposition to any
changes to improve the existing situation. The current concentration of 84%
of UK bank savings in six banks and the absence of public local banks of the
Spakassen type is largely responsible for current failings.
Bank branches in the UK at present act as facilities for collecting local
savings and then channelling them almost entirely into London; there is little
direction of such savings into local SME investments. The
millions of VAT-paying SMEs in the UK receive virtually no support from
the branches of the UK banking system except for the standard retail
service of a money transfer system.
By contrast, the more successful German economy has seven regional
banks, 453 Sparkassen (or local savings banks) and a network of 12,600
branches to provide SME loans from German savings. Each Sparkassen – all
453 of them – concentrate on providing business loans to SMEs in the area
where it is located, and each has an interest in, and commitment to,
ensuring the economic success of its native village, city or region.
Britain has nothing remotely similar nowadays, but it had such a system
until the 1880 Bank Amalgamations were put into effect, so destroying
“country banking” and paving the way for the English Clearing Banks. As Professor
Glyn Davies said in his 1979 evidence to the Wilson Committee “If Britain
had had the financial arrangements it has now at the time of the industrial
revolution, that revolution would have been still-born.”
This situation is no longer tolerable. If we are to prosper so as to compete
with powerful overseas competitors, the banking system must be reformed.
Fresh legislation should be enacted to require British banks to operate
mainly in just one of four separate categories – as retail banks, mortgage and
consumer credit banks, merchant banks, and investment credit banks. At the level of the local
community, community interest credit banks,
having the function of supporting and developing all of the local SMEs,
should be created to fulfil that function.
The Creation of Community Interest Credit Banks in Britain
The continuation of the existing banking arrangements, in which the
merchant bank gambling function is a legally allowable integrated division
of Clearing Banks with the rest of their banking business, is not a safe way
forward for the British economy, as Mervyn King has regularly warned us all.
That was the major cause of the credit crunch, because that structure
enabled British Banks to gamble with the savings and the circulating credit
of the UK on the international money, stock and bond markets. The “clever”
re-packaging of poor quality US housing debt, with the mistaken sale of
these mortgages as good quality loans when they were not, was the main
factor in causing the credit crunch.
The six major UK Clearing Banks give no priority whatsoever to providing long-term capital in
relatively small amounts to the 4.85 million SMEs of the United Kingdom.
There is not a single financial organisation in the UK which has the
objective of collecting financial savings and providing it, as required, at
local level to those millions of inventive and innovative local SMEs.
This has been the major conclusion repeatedly found by a number of high-powered
reports, most recently from the Committee to Review the Functioning of Financial Institutions
(successfully renamed the “Wilson Committee” by the British Clearing Banks
so as to imply that report was just a socialist recommendation) which emphasised
the need for patient, major long-term funding for British industry.
The industrial revolution was born from the commitment of local and
“country” banks to the SMEs which then grew into major industries.
All successful economic developments in all countries – in the UK’s
industrial revolution, in the USA, in Germany and in Japan – have depended
not just on the major industries but on the millions of SMEs
which continually provide the wellspring of small-scale services and
manufacture without which major national industries could not flourish.
It is essential that hundreds of local CICs with thousands of branches are
established throughout the United Kingdom. These local CICs should have a
“local first” commitment to the success of local SMEs which should be
provided with the funds required to provide the liquidity, working capital
and plant and equipment investment to improve their commercial
operations.
These local banks could be quickly provided by the nationalisation
of the Trustee Savings Bank and its local branches, which could be
regrouped into quasi-independent local-first CICs committed to the success
of the SMEs and industries in their local area.
© Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 6
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government
By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards
Part 6: The No-Cost Keynesian Stimulation of Demand in the Economy
An incoming Labour government could and should stimulate the economy by
restoring all the benefits (worth about £20 bn a year) which the Coalition
Government has reduced or denied to the low-paid, the sick, the disabled,
the poor and the underprivileged. The case for doing so is based not only on
social justice and on restoring the integrity of our society but on making
good the deficiency of demand that has handicapped our economy as a
consequence of austerity.
This would be achieved by creating £20 bn of consumer credit at the Bank
of England to fund the policy during that first year. The costs of that credit
creation for Government expenditure would be nil and the benefits would
be immense. If we assume the average UK tax take of about 42%,
government income would rise by about £8.4 bn; but because much of the
extra purchasing power might be spent on food and other non-taxed
necessities, the tax take might be about half of that – say 21%. On the
other hand, the extra spending would have a multiplier effect of about 2, so
that the total effect on the UK economy would be a stimulus of about
£40bn. Even allowing for a lower than average tax take, the Government
would still gain revenue of £8.4 billion, the economy would receive a
stimulus of £40 billion (a likely addition to economic growth of about 2.6%)
and many of the dire effects of the Coalition’s austerity programme would
be negated. The financial condition of Britain’s poorest would be
ameliorated; the poor would be more able to afford to eat, heat their
homes, pay their bills, and live better lives without worrying where the
next penny was coming from.
That policy could be continued in the following years but, as the additional
government taxes came in from economic recovery, the credit required to
be created would reduce accordingly eventually becoming nil within the
lifetime of the parliament as economic growth increased due to investment
credit economics.
The Credit Restoration of the Royal Bank of Scotland
The bad debts of the Bank of Scotland should be immediately purchased in
their entirety by the Bank of England, using targeted quantitative easing.
Again, it would cost the Government nothing. The Government would have
bought assets worth (say) 50% of their book value for nil expenditure. The
total bad debts of the RBS are estimated at £38 billion, so the Government
would gain assets of about £19 billion in return for no appreciable cost
whatsoever. Furthermore, the RBS would cease rejecting loan applications
from SMEs, where they are urgently needed but where about three out of
four are currently being turned away. There is no good reason why the RBS
should continue to do this, when normal business could be resumed
immediately.
Through this means, which could be applied to stabilise other British banks
as necessary, one of the main and continuing consequences of the Global
Financial Crisis – the overhang of bad debts that inhibit the banks from
lending – can be negated. Interestingly, one of Richard Werner’s major
findings from his inquiry into the reasons for the Japanese stagnation over
recent decades was the inhibiting effect of bad debts on the willingness of
the Japanese banking system to maintain an adequate level of credit
creation and therefore of liquidity. In this instance, we have the chance to
learn from Japanese mistakes. We should be clear that the objection based
on moral hazard pales into insignificance by comparison with the huge
economic advantages from pursuing this course.
Many of those who call themselves economists and many politicians who
imagine themselves to be competent will be stunned by these proposals, if
the past is any guide. As Keynes commented, “the difficulty lies not so
much in developing new ideas as in escaping from the old ones, which
ramify, for most of us brought up as we have been, into every corner of our
minds.” And as John Kenneth Galbraith, who was a member of the FDR
administration when the investment credit creation policy was adopted by
the US Government, has said, “the creation of money is so simple that the
mind is repelled.”
We should remind ourselves that there is nothing new about the creation of
credit by the Bank of England. No less than £375 bn of credit was created
to stabilise the liquidity and preserve the operation of British Clearing
Banks and £80 bn of such credit was created to support Vince Cable’s
proposal to extend business loans to industry.
The novel aspect (in British terms at least) of our proposals is that the
proposed credit is to be focused on useful social and economic objectives –
on the establishment of more prosperity among the poor and
disadvantaged, upon the minimal cost fixing of the RBS and other banks and
upon the creation of the kind of bank support for industry and commerce
that has existed for centuries in Germany, for about a century in Japan and
for about a third of a century in China.
The Mechanisms
The primary objective of the incoming Labour Government’s reforms should
be the establishment of a United Kingdom of abundant capital resources
and the placement of Britain’s future industries on a sound economic
footing. Inseparable from that first objective is the reformation of the
British banking system to ensure its future stability and effectiveness.
Another objective would be the fulfilment of the Government’s duty of care
to the people – the relief of the groups disadvantaged by the actions of the
recent Coalition Government and the restoration of full employment as a
government objective. Finally, measures should be taken to ensure the
permanence and continuity of these reforms through major changes in the
machinery of Government. We set out now our proposals for achieving
these objectives.
The Re-nationalisation of the Bank of England
The Bank of England should be brought once again under Government
control. It is unwise for any government to allow any natural monopoly to
be fully independent, and the control of credit creation is such a central
aspect of government policy that direct control is required.
The operating objectives of the Bank of England, as a central departmental
agency of government policy, will be redefined as the promotion of
economic growth and the control of inflation within the guidelines of a
national industrial and social development plan.
Gordon Brown’s proclamation of the “independence” of the central bank
was widely applauded at the time and remains a cardinal – and
unchallenged – element in policy today. Yet handing monetary policy over
to the tender care of a central bank is simply a reinforcement of the
current and increasingly discredited orthodoxy that inflation is the only
concern and proper focus of monetary policy and that its treatment is
simply a technical matter that is properly the preserve of unaccountable
bankers, and is not to be trusted to politicians. Quite apart from the
undemocratic nature of this approach, we have paid a heavy economic
price for allowing the bankers’ interest to prevail over the interests of the
economy as a whole.
It is easy to see why the bankers – and the economists who work for them –
should support this. It is less easy to see why the politicians should so
readily have accepted it. Yet the answer is fairly clear. It has suited the
politicians well to be able to argue that the travails of the economy arise as
a consequence of inexorable economic forces which must kept in check and
marshalled by expert technicians. Our governments have thereby been able
to disclaim any responsibility for policies for which they should be
ultimately responsible.
As a matter of interest, this very issue was succinctly discussed by members
of the Japanese Committee on Financial System Research (Kinyu Seido
Chosa Kai) as it considered whether to revise the 1942 Japan Law that
established the Bank of Japan’s primary objective as the promotion of
economic growth. On that Committee, Dr Shimomura represented the
Ministry of Finance, while his opposite number was Mr Shigeo Matsumota,
representing the Bank of Japan.
Dr Shimomura is reported as having “stressed the inevitable subordination
of the central bank to the government from two standpoints – that the
policy of the central bank should be managed and operated in
full coordination with the general economic policy of the Government and
that the Government on its part is called upon to hold itself responsible to
the nation for the outcome of its financial policy.”
Mr Matsumoto on the other hand “emphasised the necessity of maintaining
the independence or neutrality of the central bank from the Government on
the ground that the central bank is first of all assigned with the task of
contributing to the stabilisation of the currency value….”1‑
What is clear is that an economic policy that breaks the shackles of current
orthodoxy would necessarily have to be removed from the exclusive and
self-interested control of bankers. It would need to be driven by politicians
who saw the need to ensure that the wider interest is carried into policy
and is an essential element in setting its direction and gaining for it the
necessary support.
© Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015
- From “The Political Economy of Japanese Monetary Policy” by Thomas E Cargill, Michael M Hutchinson and Takatoshi Ito, The MIT Press, Cambridge Massachusetts and London, England, p24.
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 5
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government
By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards
Part 5 of 9 – The Two Great Traditions in Western Economic Thinking
In studying what actually happened to the Japanese economy and then testing various explanations
for consistency with the observed data, Professor Richard Werner of
Southampton University has placed himself firmly in the first of the two great traditions in
Western economic thought. That first tradition, dating from the time of
Adam Smith, derives economic conclusions from detailed observation and
inductive reasoning based upon the observed facts and data analysis. The
second tradition, most highly developed in the 20th century with the
development of mathematical economic models and more lately computers,
develops a body of deductive reasoning based upon stated theoretical
propositions.
The “bottom up” tradition of observing what is happening, building
economic understanding on the foundation of the observed circumstances
or measured data, and arguing from the observations or the data to the
economic theory is exemplified by Adam Smith’s, The Wealth of Nations.
An example of his technique is his reference to the productive power of
specialisation, which he illustrates by referring to the workers in a pin
factory, and demonstrating how, by breaking down the elements of
production into their constituent parts, a few specialised workers can
create thousands of pins a day when one man could hardly produce one pin
per day on his own. Smith’s book is a major illustration of the major
scientific principle – revived in the Renaissance – of learning by observation,
extracting the particular principle from the general, and basing theory upon
precise, real-world, observation.
The one common factor in the work of Adam Smith, and of John Maynard
Keynes, Osamu Shimomura, Kenneth Kurihara and Richard Werner is that
they all belong to the first tradition in economics, the derivation of valid
theory from detailed observation. Smith in the pin factory; Keynes in his
observation that labour markets, left to market forces, do not produce full
employment; Shimomura deriving the economic model for Japan from his
observation of the productive force of credit creation in the USA from
1938-44; the Japanese-American Kurihara – examining and discussing the
Japanese economic miracle in close-up while acting as the Fulbright
Professor to Tokyo University in 1965; the German-born and Japanese-fluent
Werner in Tokyo, working from the Bank of Japan financial data about
credit creation in Japan, and analysing it into its three key functions of
investment credit, financial credit and the presence (or lack of)
consumption credit, and then proving the predictive linkages using Granger
causative analysis – the work of all these economists is located in the great
inductive tradition of economics.
The second and more recent tradition in Western economics is the “topdown”
approach. This starts from explicitly stated but theoretical
assumptions and then proceeds logically from these to policy
recommendations, using deductive reasoning and highly developed
mathematics. A number of assumptions are made – that consumers and
investors act within perfect markets, with access to perfect information, in
a world in which perfect information has levelled out local differences. On
this basis, deductive logic arrives at economic models which appear to have
great logical validity but which – as Keynes asserted – may bear little
relation to reality. In view of the imperfect outcomes of this second
approach, as evidenced by the declining fortunes of many western
economies, there is much to be said for a return to the methods used by
Adam Smith and his great successors.
Three Practical Illustrations of the Use of Credit Creation
As we have seen, if credit creation is left to the tender mercies of self-interested
commercial banks, credit will be largely devoted to gambling on
property creating a housing and other asset bubbles so as to maximize
profits for private shareholders while the real economy languishes for want
of adequate liquidity and investment capital, and the economy as a whole is
handicapped by a shortfall in effective demand.
An incoming Labour government, however, fully understanding the use of
credit creation in the public interest, could resolve many outstanding
problems. We provide three examples of the way in which this would work
to achieve quite different kinds of objectives.
The Acceleration of British Economic Growth Through Higher Investment
This aspect of central bank credit creation is by far the most potent policy
within a government’s control. It would allow the government to create
earmarked investment credits, cost-free, for use by SMEs and other private
companies to ensure the fulfilment of the Government’s economic, social
and environmental policies.
The provision of these funds would be directed by the Bank of England,
reflecting advice from the Treasury – a technique described as “Window
Guidance” when used by the Bank of Japan in using similar mechanisms in
the 1960s and 1970s. There would need to be a bank which was, or ideally a
number of banks which were, prepared to use its local branches as taps for
local investment (as the Sparkassen in Germany are) and not just – as
currently occurs – as drains to collect local saving, taking it away for
whatever fashionable policy use the London HQ decides.
The initial creation of credit could be at the level of about 10% of GDP, that
is about £150 bn a year; multiplier effects might create an eventual new
level of commercial and industrial funding of about £300 billion. We would
expect these funds to be initially used to provide an improvement of about
£100 billion in business liquidity, about £100 billion in early new plant and
equipment investment and about £100 billion in funding higher levels of raw
materials, working capital and work in progress. If the usual level of tax
take of 42% applies to the new investment and to work in progress,
government revenue receipts could increase by about £84 billion – an
excellent return to government in addition to the overall benefit to the
economy as a whole. Furthermore, that new investment would produce a
permanent increase in output of about an extra £100 billion a year, equal to
a permanent increase in GDP of about 6.7%, and a permanent rise in
government revenue of about £42 billion a year. We think these changes
would occur within about two years.
Some economists have traditionally argued that, because an extra job in
manufacturing industry has historically created another job in the service
industries, the final effect could be twice the initial stimulus. It is indeed
likely that placing the economy on a higher growth path will enable the
under-performing assets and spare capacity in our industries to respond to
the higher levels of demand created by this stimulus.
The experience of other countries shows that investment credit economics
works by creating wealth in the productive sector of the economy. The
loans made are almost completely repaid (the failure rate is typically about
2.5%) out of the growth of the economy resulting from the additional
investment. The failure rate of these loans matters little in any case
because the loans cost nothing to create; their consequences matter,
however, because they produce their targeted effect in reducing poverty,
stabilising the banking system, and creating widespread prosperity through
many flourishing private industries in all the areas of the country.
The increase in output would obviously negate the risk that a substantial
increase in the money supply could be inflationary, as Keynes recognized
and as the Japanese experience in particular demonstrates. The
consequence of the increased money supply could well be a fall in the
international value of the pound, which could only be helpful in
ameliorating the competitiveness problem of British industry and in
ensuring readily available markets for increased British production.
Unemployment will fall to a low level. Social security payments will
automatically reduce as fuller employment becomes the norm and
Government income will cease to be disappointing, ending the need for
austerity in government expenditure and bringing to an end all of its ill
effects for our people.
© Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 4
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government
By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards
Part 4 of 9 – Shimomuran Economics
The body of developed policy that underpins Asian industrial and economic
success is not understood in the West, yet it was clearly foreshadowed in
the work of the greatest western economist of the twentieth century, John
Maynard Keynes. It is a sad reflection on western economists that the
Keynesian insights were most fully developed by the great Japanese
economist, Dr Osama Shimomura 1910-89, whose work has only recently
come to the attention of western economists by virtue of the sustained
efforts over four decades by the second author of this paper.
An indication of the extent to which Shimomura has been overlooked in the
West is the fact that his works have never been translated Into English
except by the Indian Statistical Institute1, (and even in that work the
Development Bank of Japan has edited out Shimomura’s key formulae).
Shimomura enjoys, however, a towering reputation in his own country. The
Development Bank of Japan offers a “Shimomura Fellowship” to
commemorate his life on the basis that “during his long career as an
economic scholar and critic, Dr Shimomura rose to become Japan’s most
influential post-war economist, founding a school of thought based on the
“Shimomura Theory,” which attracted numerous followers.”2
He was acknowledged, within Japan and during his lifetime, as the “brains
behind the Japanese economic miracle” – the most successful national
economic growth plan of the 20th century. Five of his published works
became available in the British Library last year but there seems to be little
interest in how Japan, in the course of a few decades, progressed from the
war-damaged, impoverished country of 1945 to become one of the most
highly developed and powerful industrial economies in the world.
Shimomura’s major contribution to macro-economics is his economic growth
model, the basis of which was that the total level of Japanese investment is
equal to the natural investment level (that is, investment financed by
savings) plus the additional investment financed by credit creation
originating at the Bank of Japan. The model illustrated the range of that
additional credit-created investment as no less than 10% to 15% of national
income a year.
It is generally agreed by most economists, following Keynes, that
investment is the major key to economic development and growth.
Shimomura’s economic model applied an extension of the Keynesian
analysis and showed that an economy could selectively increase its
investment level through an increase in investment credit at the central
bank, if that credit was earmarked for commercial and industrial
investment. The rapidity of Japanese industrial development in the 1960s
and 1970s, in apparent response to the stimulus provided by investment
credit-creation by the Bank of Japan under instructions from the
government, is widely seen in Asian economies as a vindication of
Shimomuran policies.
Professor Kenneth K Kurihara (1910-1972) – the Distinguished Professor of
Economic Theory at the State University of New York in Binghampton,
teacher of macro-economics at Princeton and Rutgers, the State University
of New Jersey, guest lecturer at the universities of Oxford and Cambridge,
and author of “The Growth Potential of the Japanese Economy” – was one
of the most influential interpreters of Shimomuran economics; he also had
the great advantage of being able to write in English. He concluded that
“if, therefore, greater investment can be financed partly by credits, there
is no need for that ‘abstinence’ which the classical economists considered
necessary for economic progress, any more than there is for that ‘austerity’
which some present day underdeveloped countries impose on already
under-consuming populations at the constant peril of social unrest. Nor is it
difficult, in such credit-creating circumstances, to agree with Keynes’
observation that investment and consumption should be regarded as
complementary rather than competitive.”3
After more than two decades of persistent stagnation, during which
Shimomuran policies were lost sight of, and supplanted by policies urged on
the Japanese by the IMF and western economists, Shimomura is now back in
favour in Japan. The Prime Minister of Japan, Shinzo Abe, announced on 19
April 2013 in a speech to the Japan National Press Club that Japan is once
again implementing Shimomuran economics – he explicitly made two
references to Dr Shimomura – in order to end the Japanese depression and
restore high growth to create once again what he described as “a Japan of
abundant capital.”4
Western economists, however, seem to be unaware of this revival of
Shimomuran economics. On the rare occasions that they have been invited
to consider the issue, they have maintained that correlation is not
causation, and that there is no evidence that the new credit created by the
Bank of Japan “caused” the observed growth in the 1960s and 1970s, or
that the cessation of that growth was the consequence of abandoning credit
creation. And there the argument might have rested except for two recent
developments.
First, the British economist Sir Clive Granger produced, in a 1969 paper in
Econometrica, a new statistical technique called Granger Predictive
Causation Analysis – an achievement that led in 2003 to his award, along
with his colleague Robert Engle, of a Nobel Prize for contributions to
economics. The Granger Causality Analysis tests the validity of predictive
causative links between two economic factors; using Granger predictive
analysis, it can be shown whether there is a predictive link between two
items of economic time series.
Second, and more recently, detailed and expert work on the course of the
Japanese economy – both its period of sustained and almost unprecedented
growth, and its subsequent period of stubborn stagnation – was undertaken
by Professor Richard Werner, professor of economics at the University of
Southampton. Professor Werner originated the term “quantitative easing”
and in 1991 predicted the imminent ‘collapse’ of the Japanese banking
system and the threat of the “greatest recession since the Great
Depression”. He is a specialist in the Japanese economy and became the
first Shimomura Fellow at the Research Institute for Capital Formation at
the Development Bank of Japan where he spent ten years in the 1990s.
Professor Werner has applied Granger Predictive Causation Analysis to the
Japanese data over a long period and has shown in his book “New Paradigm
in Macroeconomics” – that there is a clear Granger causation predictive link
between investment credit creation at the Bank of Japan and subsequent
rates of Japanese economic growth, both positive and negative. He also
found that the causative link that is so clear in the case of investment
credit creation does not hold good in respect of any other of the
candidates, such as interest rates, structural changes, and so on, that are
often advanced as potential explanations for the vagaries of the Japanese
economy over five decades. Significantly, Werner also found that excessive
credit creation where that credit is not earmarked for use in new
investment in productive capacity will finds its outlet in speculation and the
creation of asset bubbles, as occurred in Japan from 1986-91.
Werner’s use of the Granger technique and the conclusions he is able to
draw allow us to say with certainty that the use of investment credit
creation has been the essential element in determining the rate of growth
for the Japanese economy. Empirical observation and the analysis of the
observed data allow for no other explanation. It is on that basis that we can
extrapolate from the Japanese experience, as identified by Werner, to
western economies, and say that – since advanced economies function very
similarly, whether in Japan or elsewhere – the solution to the poor
performance and lagging development of western economies is the adoption
of investment credit economics, which is fully capable of reversing the ill effects,
including the damage to personal incomes and the social fabric, of
austerity.
1 A reference to that inadequate translation of what is perhaps Shimomura’s most significant
books, Seicho Seisaku No Kihon Mondai (Basic Problems in Growth Policy, 1961) can be found
http://books.google.co.uk/books/about/Basic_Problems_of_Economic_Growth_Policy.html?
id=DyNjHQAACAAJ&redir_esc=y
2 See http://www.dbj.jp/ricf/en/fellowship/
3 See “The Growth Potential of the Japanese Economy” (John Hopkins Press Maryland 1971), pp.
137-138
4 http://www.kantei.go.jp/foreign/96_abe/statement/201304/19speech_e.html
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 3
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government
By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards
Part 3 of 9 – The Different Uses of Credit Creation
Credit creation when properly deployed can serve five main purposes, each
having major and differential effects on the real economy. We cannot
expect, and nor can an incoming Labour government, to produce better
economic outcomes unless we understand the differences between them.
First, credit creation may be undertaken (and usually is) for purely
speculative purposes. Its principal purpose and effect is to fund housing
purchase and speculative financial transactions; it is often the main factor
in the development of housing, land and asset bubbles. It is this aspect of
credit creation that attracts most attention in today’s economy and which is
the main focus of the banks’ activities, since it is the easiest business to
attract, the most secure (since mortgages guarantee the value of the credit
in most cases) and the most profitable.
It is also the principal factor in stimulating inflation; housing values, in
particular, rise sharply as large volumes of credit-created money flow into
the housing market, and the consequent asset inflation is inevitably
followed by consumer led inflation as home-owners use the increased value
of their equity to increase consumption. This is, of course, of great
significance, given that the control of inflation is the prime and virtually
only focus of macro-economic policy; it suggests that the use of interest
rates to tighten monetary conditions, impacting as it does on the whole
economy, fails to address effectively and accurately the real cause of
inflationary pressures and is an unnecessarily broad and badly focused
instrument that does great damage to the wider economy at the same time.
The overwhelming dominance of credit creation for speculative purposes –
for both housing and other financial transactions – has other adverse
features. It distorts the desired operation of the economy by diverting
investment capital away from productive purposes, and by creating asset
bubbles in both residential housing and financial assets, not least in western
stock exchanges; and the resultant constant inflationary impetus then has
to be restrained by measures such as higher interest rates, so that the
chances of greater innovation and productivity are further prejudiced.
Despite all of these downsides, credit creation for speculative purposes as a
major economic factor impacting on the real economy is virtually ignored
by our policy-makers, except to the extent that it is seen as perfectly
normal and relatively benign.
The second kind of credit creation operates as an important element in
demand management. It is used to raise purchasing power by putting more
money in people’s pockets, and thereby can help to resolve the problem of
deficient demand that Keynes identified as the key element in the Great
Depression and that continues to characterise recessionary conditions today.
It would normally be undertaken by the banks, under direction from the
central bank or the Treasury, though it could also be undertaken directly by
the central bank or the government. It is little used in today’s Britain, not
surprisingly, when the Coalition government does not recognise a deficiency
of demand as the feature of a recessionary situation that needs correction.
It has, however, returned to favour as a counter-recessionary instrument in
the thinking of some of our leading monetary economists. Keynes had
suggested in the 1930s – half-jokingly but so as to make a serious point –
that a valuable counter-recessionary outcome could be obtained by burying
money in the ground and then paying firms to employ people to dig it up.
Their increased income would represent a significant increase in purchasing
power and therefore demand.
Such a policy today is often pejoratively characterised as “helicopter
money” – the notion that demand could be raised if pound notes were
scattered from the air – but has been seriously analysed by economists such
as Adair Turner and Michael Woodford who have reached the point of
debating whether it would best be delivered by fiscal measures (such as tax
cuts) or by monetary policy (essentially printing money).1
Credit creation undertaken to raise demand does not mean that it cannot
serve other purposes at the same time; or, to put it in another way, credit
creation undertake for other purposes, such as funding the purchase of
assets or providing capital for investment, may well also have the additional
effect of lifting the level of demand. As we shall see, the crucial question
is then as to whether the increased demand is merely inflationary or is
matched by increased output.
Thirdly, credit creation can also be undertaken for the purpose of stabilising
the financial system; this technique, which has been called Quantitative
Easing over recent times, has been implemented by governments in both
the UK and the US, and was meant to remedy – in the wake of the Global
Financial Crisis – the precarious situation of an otherwise bankrupt financial
system. In the case of the UK, the policy took the form of the Bank of
England’s £375bn of financial credit to stabilise the UK Clearing Banks but it
did nothing to benefit the wider economy. The greater proportion of that
sum was used by the banks to strengthen their balance sheets (and to
resume paying large bonuses); very little found its way into lending to the
Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises that desperately needed help in
maintaining adequate liquidity (and for plant and equipment investment).
Credit creation for the purpose of funding major innovative programmes –
sometimes called Government Credit Creation (GCC) – is the fourth kind of
credit creation and is designed to enable major innovative structural
economic change, such as the invention of the atomic bomb, the mass production
of synthetic rubber in the US in 1940-44, and President Obama’s
Energy Initiative; it is often resorted to in wartime. The intention is to
stimulate innovation in the public sector or infrastructure area of the
economy and to undertake large-scale projects that are vitally important to
the economy but are too large or not commercially rewarding enough to
attract private capital.
This kind of credit creation for public purpose is being supplanted
increasingly in Britain today by Public/Private Partnerships, on the specious
ground that they offer better value to the taxpayer; the reality is that they
are much more expensive than publicly funded projects, but they have the
great merit in the eyes of right-wing governments of offering fat profits to
their friends in private industry.
The fifth and, for our purposes, most interesting and important form of
credit creation is usually called Investment Credit Creation (ICC). This form
of credit is targeted at increasing investment in the plant and equipment
level in private industry, with the goal of encouraging productivity
improvement, accelerating the rate of economic growth and providing full
employment. Investment Credit Creation is usually delivered through the
local banks (if you have any) at the behest of the central bank and the
government. It is this aspect of credit creation that has been virtually
ignored in western economies over recent decades but which offers by far
the best prospect of breaking out of our seemingly irreversible economic
decline.
There is today virtually no understanding in Britain and other western
countries of how Investment Credit Creation functions and of the benefits it
can bring to economic development. The provision of credit – that is, bank
lending – is seen almost exclusively in terms of its capacity to stimulate
inflation and is seen therefore as a potential threat rather than as an
essential element in producing a better economic performance.
This is notwithstanding Keynes’ perceptive assertion that there is no reason
why the provision of credit for the purpose of productive investment should
not precede the increase in output that it is intended to produce, provided
that the increase occurs over an appropriate time frame. Other economies
have understood and benefited from this insight and have used Investment
Credit Creation to stimulate growth, without being inhibited by the
conviction that any increase in the money supply must necessarily be
inflationary.
There are, in fact, many persuasive instances from both recent history and
from other countries of the successful deployment of Investment Credit
Creation. One of the most striking examples of the use of credit creation,
not to inflate the property market for private profit as is done in the West
at present, but to stimulate rapid industrial growth, was provided by the
United States at the outbreak of the Second World War, when Roosevelt
used the two years before Pearl Harbour to provide virtually unlimited
capital to American industry – simply by printing money – so that the
country could rapidly increase its military capability.
Roosevelt encountered the usual objections from conventional economists
but the exigencies of war and his own political strength and will prevailed.
The results were spectacular and hugely significant. American industrial
output grew on average by an unprecedented 12.2% per annum from 1938
to 1944 – an outcome that went a long way towards enabling the US, and
the Allies more generally, to win the Second World War.
An equally impressive instance is provided by Japan in the 1960s and 1970s,
when Japanese industry was enabled by similar means to grow at a rapid
rate so as to dominate the world market for mass-produced manufactured
goods. Western economists have typically shown no interest in how this was
done and are almost totally ignorant of the work of leading growth expert
economists such as the Japanese Osamu Shimomura and the American-
Japanese Kenneth Kurihara. We shall look in more detail 2 later at exactly
how Investment Credit Creation was specifically implemented by the Bank
of Japan, at the behest of the government and following the advice of
Shimomura and his colleagues, and accordingly brought about the Japanese
economic miracle.
More recently, China has used similar techniques to finance the rapid
expansion of Chinese manufacturing. The Chinese central bank, and their
provincial counterparts, under instructions from the government, makes
credit available to Chinese enterprises that can demonstrate their ability to
comply with the government’s economic priorities. Enterprises that wish to
build or buy new capacity in compliance with the overall industrial strategy
are provided with the required investment capital, obtained through cost-free
credit creation; Chinese manufacturing capacity in particular has
largely been funded by such government-authorised new credit, as has the
huge purchasing programme of strategic assets from around the world that
is currently being undertaken by Chinese enterprises. This is admittedly, in
principle at least, easier to bring about in a totalitarian regime than in the
UK, but in practice there is nothing to stop a British government from
requiring the central bank, as the Chinese have done, to create cost-free
credit for specific (and productive) purposes.
Other Asian countries, such as Korea and Taiwan, have applied similar
policies in order to produce rapid industrial growth. Typically, however,
Western economists have arrogantly assumed that these successful
economies have nothing to teach us, and are easily dismissed as
undeveloped economies relying for competitive advantage on cheap labour;
the reality is, of course, that these economies are, as a consequence of the
rapid economic growth and industrial development made possible by
Investment Credit Creation, delivering incomes and living standards to their
populations that are approaching and in some cases surpassing those in the
West.
1 See www.voxeu.org/article/helicopter-money-policy-option
© Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015