Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 3
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government
By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards
Part 3 of 9 – The Different Uses of Credit Creation
Credit creation when properly deployed can serve five main purposes, each
having major and differential effects on the real economy. We cannot
expect, and nor can an incoming Labour government, to produce better
economic outcomes unless we understand the differences between them.
First, credit creation may be undertaken (and usually is) for purely
speculative purposes. Its principal purpose and effect is to fund housing
purchase and speculative financial transactions; it is often the main factor
in the development of housing, land and asset bubbles. It is this aspect of
credit creation that attracts most attention in today’s economy and which is
the main focus of the banks’ activities, since it is the easiest business to
attract, the most secure (since mortgages guarantee the value of the credit
in most cases) and the most profitable.
It is also the principal factor in stimulating inflation; housing values, in
particular, rise sharply as large volumes of credit-created money flow into
the housing market, and the consequent asset inflation is inevitably
followed by consumer led inflation as home-owners use the increased value
of their equity to increase consumption. This is, of course, of great
significance, given that the control of inflation is the prime and virtually
only focus of macro-economic policy; it suggests that the use of interest
rates to tighten monetary conditions, impacting as it does on the whole
economy, fails to address effectively and accurately the real cause of
inflationary pressures and is an unnecessarily broad and badly focused
instrument that does great damage to the wider economy at the same time.
The overwhelming dominance of credit creation for speculative purposes –
for both housing and other financial transactions – has other adverse
features. It distorts the desired operation of the economy by diverting
investment capital away from productive purposes, and by creating asset
bubbles in both residential housing and financial assets, not least in western
stock exchanges; and the resultant constant inflationary impetus then has
to be restrained by measures such as higher interest rates, so that the
chances of greater innovation and productivity are further prejudiced.
Despite all of these downsides, credit creation for speculative purposes as a
major economic factor impacting on the real economy is virtually ignored
by our policy-makers, except to the extent that it is seen as perfectly
normal and relatively benign.
The second kind of credit creation operates as an important element in
demand management. It is used to raise purchasing power by putting more
money in people’s pockets, and thereby can help to resolve the problem of
deficient demand that Keynes identified as the key element in the Great
Depression and that continues to characterise recessionary conditions today.
It would normally be undertaken by the banks, under direction from the
central bank or the Treasury, though it could also be undertaken directly by
the central bank or the government. It is little used in today’s Britain, not
surprisingly, when the Coalition government does not recognise a deficiency
of demand as the feature of a recessionary situation that needs correction.
It has, however, returned to favour as a counter-recessionary instrument in
the thinking of some of our leading monetary economists. Keynes had
suggested in the 1930s – half-jokingly but so as to make a serious point –
that a valuable counter-recessionary outcome could be obtained by burying
money in the ground and then paying firms to employ people to dig it up.
Their increased income would represent a significant increase in purchasing
power and therefore demand.
Such a policy today is often pejoratively characterised as “helicopter
money” – the notion that demand could be raised if pound notes were
scattered from the air – but has been seriously analysed by economists such
as Adair Turner and Michael Woodford who have reached the point of
debating whether it would best be delivered by fiscal measures (such as tax
cuts) or by monetary policy (essentially printing money).1
Credit creation undertaken to raise demand does not mean that it cannot
serve other purposes at the same time; or, to put it in another way, credit
creation undertake for other purposes, such as funding the purchase of
assets or providing capital for investment, may well also have the additional
effect of lifting the level of demand. As we shall see, the crucial question
is then as to whether the increased demand is merely inflationary or is
matched by increased output.
Thirdly, credit creation can also be undertaken for the purpose of stabilising
the financial system; this technique, which has been called Quantitative
Easing over recent times, has been implemented by governments in both
the UK and the US, and was meant to remedy – in the wake of the Global
Financial Crisis – the precarious situation of an otherwise bankrupt financial
system. In the case of the UK, the policy took the form of the Bank of
England’s £375bn of financial credit to stabilise the UK Clearing Banks but it
did nothing to benefit the wider economy. The greater proportion of that
sum was used by the banks to strengthen their balance sheets (and to
resume paying large bonuses); very little found its way into lending to the
Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises that desperately needed help in
maintaining adequate liquidity (and for plant and equipment investment).
Credit creation for the purpose of funding major innovative programmes –
sometimes called Government Credit Creation (GCC) – is the fourth kind of
credit creation and is designed to enable major innovative structural
economic change, such as the invention of the atomic bomb, the mass production
of synthetic rubber in the US in 1940-44, and President Obama’s
Energy Initiative; it is often resorted to in wartime. The intention is to
stimulate innovation in the public sector or infrastructure area of the
economy and to undertake large-scale projects that are vitally important to
the economy but are too large or not commercially rewarding enough to
attract private capital.
This kind of credit creation for public purpose is being supplanted
increasingly in Britain today by Public/Private Partnerships, on the specious
ground that they offer better value to the taxpayer; the reality is that they
are much more expensive than publicly funded projects, but they have the
great merit in the eyes of right-wing governments of offering fat profits to
their friends in private industry.
The fifth and, for our purposes, most interesting and important form of
credit creation is usually called Investment Credit Creation (ICC). This form
of credit is targeted at increasing investment in the plant and equipment
level in private industry, with the goal of encouraging productivity
improvement, accelerating the rate of economic growth and providing full
employment. Investment Credit Creation is usually delivered through the
local banks (if you have any) at the behest of the central bank and the
government. It is this aspect of credit creation that has been virtually
ignored in western economies over recent decades but which offers by far
the best prospect of breaking out of our seemingly irreversible economic
decline.
There is today virtually no understanding in Britain and other western
countries of how Investment Credit Creation functions and of the benefits it
can bring to economic development. The provision of credit – that is, bank
lending – is seen almost exclusively in terms of its capacity to stimulate
inflation and is seen therefore as a potential threat rather than as an
essential element in producing a better economic performance.
This is notwithstanding Keynes’ perceptive assertion that there is no reason
why the provision of credit for the purpose of productive investment should
not precede the increase in output that it is intended to produce, provided
that the increase occurs over an appropriate time frame. Other economies
have understood and benefited from this insight and have used Investment
Credit Creation to stimulate growth, without being inhibited by the
conviction that any increase in the money supply must necessarily be
inflationary.
There are, in fact, many persuasive instances from both recent history and
from other countries of the successful deployment of Investment Credit
Creation. One of the most striking examples of the use of credit creation,
not to inflate the property market for private profit as is done in the West
at present, but to stimulate rapid industrial growth, was provided by the
United States at the outbreak of the Second World War, when Roosevelt
used the two years before Pearl Harbour to provide virtually unlimited
capital to American industry – simply by printing money – so that the
country could rapidly increase its military capability.
Roosevelt encountered the usual objections from conventional economists
but the exigencies of war and his own political strength and will prevailed.
The results were spectacular and hugely significant. American industrial
output grew on average by an unprecedented 12.2% per annum from 1938
to 1944 – an outcome that went a long way towards enabling the US, and
the Allies more generally, to win the Second World War.
An equally impressive instance is provided by Japan in the 1960s and 1970s,
when Japanese industry was enabled by similar means to grow at a rapid
rate so as to dominate the world market for mass-produced manufactured
goods. Western economists have typically shown no interest in how this was
done and are almost totally ignorant of the work of leading growth expert
economists such as the Japanese Osamu Shimomura and the American-
Japanese Kenneth Kurihara. We shall look in more detail 2 later at exactly
how Investment Credit Creation was specifically implemented by the Bank
of Japan, at the behest of the government and following the advice of
Shimomura and his colleagues, and accordingly brought about the Japanese
economic miracle.
More recently, China has used similar techniques to finance the rapid
expansion of Chinese manufacturing. The Chinese central bank, and their
provincial counterparts, under instructions from the government, makes
credit available to Chinese enterprises that can demonstrate their ability to
comply with the government’s economic priorities. Enterprises that wish to
build or buy new capacity in compliance with the overall industrial strategy
are provided with the required investment capital, obtained through cost-free
credit creation; Chinese manufacturing capacity in particular has
largely been funded by such government-authorised new credit, as has the
huge purchasing programme of strategic assets from around the world that
is currently being undertaken by Chinese enterprises. This is admittedly, in
principle at least, easier to bring about in a totalitarian regime than in the
UK, but in practice there is nothing to stop a British government from
requiring the central bank, as the Chinese have done, to create cost-free
credit for specific (and productive) purposes.
Other Asian countries, such as Korea and Taiwan, have applied similar
policies in order to produce rapid industrial growth. Typically, however,
Western economists have arrogantly assumed that these successful
economies have nothing to teach us, and are easily dismissed as
undeveloped economies relying for competitive advantage on cheap labour;
the reality is, of course, that these economies are, as a consequence of the
rapid economic growth and industrial development made possible by
Investment Credit Creation, delivering incomes and living standards to their
populations that are approaching and in some cases surpassing those in the
West.
1 See www.voxeu.org/article/helicopter-money-policy-option
© Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 2
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government
By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards
Part 2 of 9: Stimulating Wealth Creation
If we are to find that better way, we must clearly understand the failures
and deficiencies of what has gone before. A major milestone in that quest
for understanding was reached earlier this year when the Bank of England,
in an article published in its first quarterly bulletin for the year1 became
the first significant central bank to acknowledge that the vast proportion of
money in our economy (calculated by the authors at 97% of the total money
supply) is created by the banks. This admission, which has been hotly
contested and denied by bankers and economists for decades, if not
centuries, casts a whole new light on the meaning of money and its
significance for economic policy, and is the key to a new approach – not
only as a response to recession – but as the foundation of a successful
economic policy.
We need not explore here the mechanisms by which the banks create
credit; suffice to say that they are well set out in the Bank of England
paper, and in the end amount to the simple fact that the banks are not
simply intermediaries, bringing savers and lenders together. They do not
lend money deposited with them but instead lend money that they
themselves create by making book entries unsupported by anything other
than their willingness to lend. But while the mechanisms may be simple,
the implications for policy are huge.
The facts that the quantity of money is almost entirely a function of bank
policy and that its continuing but regulated growth is the normal and
required condition for a well-functioning economy suggest strongly that the
conventional treatment of money as a neutral factor in economic policy is
completely mistaken. Current monetarist orthodoxy treats the money
supply as reflecting more or less automatically the needs of the real
economy, and impacting on it only in the sense that, if it is allowed to grow
too fast, it will generate inflation. The reality is, however, that the rate of
growth in the money supply is not just a function of the level of real
economic activity but is, as we shall see and according to the purposes to
which it is put, an important determinant of that level.
It is worth registering at this point that the banks’ remarkable monopoly
power to create (or “print”) money is exercised entirely in the interests of
profits for their own shareholders rather than of the economy as a whole.
It might be thought that this private exploitation of such an important
power would warrant the most careful public scrutiny, yet it attracts
virtually no attention from policymakers, other than in terms of countering
inflation; the Coalition government prefers to focus on reducing
government spending, as the supposedly essential feature of macroeconomic
policy.
They thereby totally overlook the fact that it is extraordinarily important
for the purposes of economic policy-making as a whole to understand the
impact of private money-creation on this scale and, in particular, to analyse
the purposes for which that credit is created.
A Labour government should no longer, in other words, accept that credit
creation by the banks is benign, and automatically serves – because it is
allegedly self-regulating – the public interest; a more effective economic
policy depends crucially on an acknowledgment that credit creation (and
therefore the whole of monetary policy) is hugely important and impacts
directly and substantially on the development of the real economy, and can
be made to serve a variety of wider economic interests rather than simply
those of private profit-seeking bank shareholders. A Labour government
that took this position would surely be encouraged to find that, on this
issue, public opinion had got there first.
Keynes was well aware of the fact, and of the almost unlimited potential,
of credit creation by the banks and recognised it as an important element in
macroeconomic policy. His pre-war contention that “there are no intrinsic
reasons for the scarcity of capital” is supported by compelling evidence, not
least now by the Bank of England’s recognition that money is created by the
banks from nothing. What should now be fully recognised, however, is that
the purposes of credit creation could and should extend well beyond the
funding of house purchase, which is currently its major feature.
Credit creation at the central bank, if properly directed and managed, can
be used to selectively increase the private investment level of the country,
as has previously occurred in all very high-growth economies, and as could
happen in Britain.
1Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, 2014, Q1 “Money Creation in the Modern Economy” by
Michael McLeay, Amar Radia and Ryland Thomas of the Bank’s Monetary Analysis Directorate.
© Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government – Part 1
Economic Policies for an Incoming Labour Government
By Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards
Part 1 of 9: The Coalition Government’s Failed Austerity Programme
The outcome of the next general election cannot be confidently predicted but one thing is clear; the odds on both a Labour election victory and a successful term in office would be greatly increased if the Labour leadership had the confidence and courage to develop and deliver a convincing alternative economic policy.
At present, Ed Miliband and Ed Balls seem inhibited from attacking the
failed policies of austerity (to which George Osborne claims there is no
alternative) and are content to focus on policy in other areas as a means of avoiding any real debate on economic policy. Yet there is, as both
experience and reason demand, a growing consensus that austerity has
failed and, as a consequence, an urgent need for Labour to describe clearly what an alternative and better policy should be and how it would operate.
The purpose of these articles is to identify one of the basic and central
issues on which that successful alternative policy should be developed. A full understanding and adoption of the proposals advanced here would allow the Labour leadership, in the run-up to the election, to attack the
Coalition’s economic record with greater conviction and confidence, and
would provide the launching-pad in government for a long-delayed and
hence urgently needed restoration of Britain’s economic fortunes.
Not A Moment Too Soon
The new direction that an incoming Labour government must adopt will
come not a moment too soon. The damage done by the Coalition
government is cumulative and fundamental, and extends beyond purely
economic failure to social dislocation and political disintegration.
In economic terms George Osborne’s record is appalling. The so-called
recovery has been delayed unnecessarily for more than half a decade and means that a return to pre-2008 living standards is still many years away.
Median GDP is still 3% below 2007 levels, and since the population has
increased by3%, that means an average fall in individual incomes of 6%.
The decline of the productive sector and particularly of manufacturing has meant that only 10% of our GDP is now accounted for by manufacturing -the lowest proportion of any major developed economy – and our share of world trade has fallen to just 2.7%.
Coalition polices have resulted in the sharpest fall in living standards in
more than 60 years. According to data from the Institute of Fiscal Studies, average wages have fallen by over £1,600 since 2010, at an average rate of over £530 a year. The pre-Coalition reduction in median income (not the same as average wages, but an acceptable proxy), can be calculated at about £5,400 over thirty years (1980 to 2010) – about £180 a year – so that the Coalition has produced a reduction in worker incomes of almost three times the previous trend.
But these figures relate only to the working population, and take no
account of the reduction in unemployment and disability benefits, the
denial of benefits to mothers seeking work because they have not been
employed during the previous two years, and the exclusion from the data
for both the employed and unemployed of the growing practice of zero hours contracts, all of which mean that the real extent of income cuts is
much larger than official figures indicate.
The burden imposed on working people has not of course been shared by the wealthiest people in our society. According to an Oxfam report1, the richest 5 families in Britain have more wealth than the poorest 20% of the population. That level of inequality is unprecedented since records began in the UK.
In an even more recent report2, Oxfam also reports that the Coalition’s
welfare cuts have pushed 1.75 million of the UK’s poorest households
deeper into poverty, suffering an absolute cut in their income in the past
three years and leaving them struggling to cover food and energy bills.
The national scandal that millions of children in the UK are going to bed hungry is not some accidental by-product of Coalition policy. It is the inevitable and deliberate consequence of policies pursued by a government that is “of the privileged, by the privileged, for the privileged”.
The disadvantaged poor – the disabled, the sick and the unemployed – have suffered, through cuts in their benefits, the greatest burdens in dealing with the recession. SCOPE, the charity supporting disabled people, have shown, for example, that 600,000 people in the UK lost a total of £2.62 billion pounds a year from Monday 8 April 2013 as a result of the Coalition Government abolishing the Disability Living Allowance (DLA) and introducing the new Personal Independence Payment (PIP), with tighter eligibility criteria and a controversial new assessment. The purpose of that change is not to improve service or to make things more fair but simply to save money. The lack of concern for the most disadvantaged in our society was compounded by the amazingly (and deliberately) inaccurate statements about incapacity benefit made by Ian Duncan Smith.
Coalition policies have disproportionately affected women, who are
more often found in lower-paid occupations and in the caring
professions. An analysis of Treasury data by House of Commons Library
researchers in 2012 showed that £11.1bn of the £14.9bn raised from the
five spending reviews since 2010 comes from women even though they earn less than men on average. Planned changes to tax credits, child benefits and public sector pensions were largely to blame. They came shortly after the government announced plans to cut the 50p top rate of tax for all those earning over £150,000.
A Failed Banking System
The failures of the Coalition government have extended into other areas of policy. One of the principal reasons for both the excesses that led to the Global Financial Crisis and the difficulty we have had in recovering from recession has been the absence of a responsible and supportive financial-industrial banking system in the United Kingdom. The Coalition Government acknowledged as much in “The Coalition: our programme for government”3 where they promised that, “We will reform the banking system to avoid a repeat of the financial crisis, to promote a competitive economy, to protect and sustain jobs”.
None of this has been done. There has been no reform of the banking
system with the result that, as Mervyn King has regularly warned, a repeat of the financial crisis is still a major risk.
They further promised that “We will introduce a banking levy and seek a
detailed agreement on implementation.” The banking levy was introduced in 2010 and was intended to raise £2.5 bn, but has raised nothing like that sum. In the 2014 Budget, George Osborne restructured the levy to provide maximum limits for individual banks and five bands, which meant a cut that is disproportionally beneficial to the very largest banks.
They also undertook to “bring forward detailed proposals for robust action to tackle unacceptable bonuses in the financial services sector; in
developing these proposals, we will ensure they are effective in reducing
risk.” Less than six months after the Coalition came into Government, the proposal to deal with bonuses was abandoned. Bonuses are back with a vengeance.
A fourth promise to “bring forward detailed proposals to foster diversity in
financial services, promote mutuals and create a more competitive banking industry” produced no action whatsoever, while a fifth to “develop effective proposals to ensure the flow of credit to viable SMEs … which will include consideration of both a major loan guarantee scheme and the use of net lending targets for the nationalised banks” produced an extra £80 bn of re-discounting of loans by banks, part of which may have proved useful to some banks who wished to reduce the bank levy, but which nevertheless produced a fall in loans to SMEs of about £56bn.
The failure to take effective action on any of these issues has been, as we shall see later, hugely detrimental to any attempt to correct one of the main deficiencies in the management of the British economy. The failures were compounded by the fate of the Parliamentary Commission on Banking Standards which was established in July 2012, following the LIBOR-rigging crisis. The Commission’s report was set aside by politicians who showed themselves anxious to find reasons to shy away from the necessary reforms. It was claimed that such reforms had been rendered unnecessary by reforms already being implemented, that they would damage the competitiveness of the City and cost jobs, and that they would harm the banks’ ability to support the rest of the economy.
The UK’s competitiveness will be threatened in the long-term by this
indifference to the dangers associated with poor banking standards and
culture. If the arguments against complacency and inaction have not been heeded now, when the crisis in banking standards has been laid bare, they are yet more certain to be ignored in the future when memories have faded.
It should be understood, however, that the real problem with British
banking is not about dubious ethics but that it does not, unlike foreign
banks, see the funding of investment in productive capacity as its main
function. The right ethics with the wrong agenda is no recipe for British
economic recovery.
The list of failures demonstrates one central theme; because the Coalition Government does not understand the process of wealth creation at all, their focus is on the side-issue of making economies in the budgeted cost of government. Their obsession with the objective of achieving a balanced budget blinds them to the fact that there is a much better way to govern Britain – a way that increases the wealth and welfare of all, as we will illustrate in the following articles in this series.
1 www.theguardian.com/business/2014/mar/17/oxfam-report-scale-britain-growing-financial-inequality?
CMP=EMCNEWEML6619I2
2 www.theguardian.com/politics/2014/apr/22/welfare-cuts-drive-uk-poorest-poverty-oxfam
3 www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/78977/ _programme_for_government.pdf
© Bryan Gould and George Tait Edwards 2015
A Fair Deal for Christchurch
The Christchurch earthquake was a catastrophe that was national in its impact and significance but that required the people of Christchurch to pay its terrible price. In the four years that have since elapsed, they have had to shoulder the burden of rebuilding shattered lives and a devastated environment.
There has been no shortage of sympathy and encouragement from the rest of the country, and the government has played its part in financing the restoration of essential infrastructure. But the government’s help – provided to Christchurch on behalf of all the people of New Zealand – has been limited by a hard-headed and largely artificial distinction between what is seen as properly the responsibility of central government and what falls to be dealt with by Christchurch itself.
We now see the impact of that distinction. It means that the people of Christchurch must face a substantial financial burden on their own, in addition to the other losses they have suffered. They are to face substantial rate increases over the next three years and their city’s finances will suffer from a further loss of income as a result of the forced sale of up to $750 million worth of city assets – assets built up over many years.
They are faced with the need to shoulder these burdens because the law, as presently defined, takes no account of their special circumstances and requires them, come what may, to balance their books. The people of New Zealand, through their government, may in other words offer sympathy, but when it comes to costs, Christchurch must – from this point on – take responsibility for re-building the city on its own.
The government’s position on this issue is hard to fathom. No one doubts that the national economy has benefited greatly from the investment that has been made and will be made in re-building the city. Our GDP growth, and the level of economic activity, have been stimulated by the increase in public funding; the earthquake forced the government’s hand to increase public spending that they would, for ideological reasons, not otherwise have undertaken.
The re-building of Christchurch, however funded, will continue to provide great benefits to the national economy in terms of employment and output. But the priority given by the government to the short-term problem of reducing its own deficit means that it is unwilling to invest in gaining the further benefits potentially available to the national economy from not leaving the people of Christchurch to find the money on their own.
There must be the suspicion that the government is not unhappy at the prospect of asset sales and the opportunity thereby offered to private investors to make a profit. But, setting aside issues of fairness and national solidarity, the government’s stance is in any case hard to justify in purely economic terms.
We can see this clearly when we examine the responses of governments around the world to crises of various sorts. In the aftermath of the Global Financial Crisis, and the threat then posed to the stability of the banking system, governments like those in the US and UK had no hesitation in creating new money to bail out the banks and to get the economy moving again.
The US Federal Reserve has created no less than $3.7 trillion of new money – so-called “quantitative easing” – and the Bank of England has done likewise to the tune of £350 billion.
The Bank of Japan, at the behest of the Japanese government, has created huge quantities of credit directed to productive investment and even the European Central Bank – so long demanding austerity and reduced government deficits – has changed course dramatically.
In New Zealand, we saw our own smaller version of the willingness to bail out financial institutions in the $1.6 billion help provided to South Canterbury Finance. If it can be done to help the banks and finance companies, why can’t it be done to help the people of Christchurch – especially when that investment would provide such a good return to the economy as a whole and wouldn’t just disappear into the balance sheets of financial institutions?
There is, after all, a powerful economic pedigree for such an approach. John Maynard Keynes famously articulated two great insights. First, he said, while there are obviously intrinsic reasons for a scarcity of land, there is no intrinsic reason – in a country that is sovereign in respect of the creation of money – for a scarcity of capital. And secondly, he observed, the creation of credit for productive purposes will not be inflationary if the increased production it is designed to bring about actually materialises.
And, for those who are still nervous about the government stepping in to help in this way, consider this. If we don’t object to the huge volumes of new credit for housing purchase created for their own purposes by the banks, why should we be so reluctant to see the government act on a much smaller scale in the public interest to help the economy as a whole and the people of Christchurch?
That would be the proper response on a national scale to what is a national and not just a Christchurch issue.
Bryan Gould
1 March 2015
A Slow-Burning Revolution
As the world struggles to deal with threatening outbreaks of violence – most dangerously, in the Middle East and the Ukraine – another less dramatic and slower-burning revolution is getting under way. This revolution does not threaten violence – but it does promise change, and almost certainly change for the better.
The revolution that is gathering pace is a shift in understanding and increasingly in policy. What we are now beginning to see is the painfully slow and invariably reluctant abandonment – in the face of evidence that is now impossible to ignore – of an economic orthodoxy that has dominated the global economy for nearly four decades.
The late 1970s saw, as we know, the development of what came to be known as the “Washington consensus” – a neo-classical economic policy orthodoxy that proved a hugely valuable travelling companion for neo-liberal politics. It was driven by the rejection of Keynesian interventionism, a faith in the infallibility of the market, and the conviction that the most that could be asked of macro-economic policy was to use monetary policy, responsibility for which was to be delegated to bankers, to control the money supply in order to restrain inflation. Government was to have a limited role, merely holding the ring while unchallengeable “free-market” forces enjoyed free rein.
This approach was given huge practical impetus when the United States and the United Kingdom decided to float their currencies and to remove exchange controls. The ability to move capital at will across national boundaries allowed international investors not only to disregard and bypass national governments but also to threaten them that they would lose essential investment if they did not comply with the investors’ demands. This shifted the balance of power dramatically in the direction of international capital, and – most significantly – was accompanied by a huge transfer of power away from governments and in favour of banks and financial institutions.
The paradox of the monetarist policy that was seen as centrally important and that supposedly focused on controlling the money supply was that the money supply was in fact almost entirely a function of virtually unlimited and therefore irresponsible lending by the banks who had moved in to displace building societies as the principal lenders for house purchase. The end result of what must have seemed to the banks like the realisation of the alchemist’s dream was of course the Global Financial Crisis and the ensuing recession.
True to form, however, the response to recession was not a rejection of neo-classical economics but an improbable assertion that the crisis had been caused by excessive government spending rather than irresponsible bank lending. The proper remedy for recession, we were told, was austerity and, in particular, a constant downward pressure on government spending. We have now had ample opportunity to test this assertion in the light of practical experience.
The answer, whatever may still be the received wisdom in Berlin or London, is unequivocal. As we learnt from the Great Depression, but then forgot, austerity is precisely the worst possible response to recession. The evidence for that does not depend only on the testimony of those who have long warned that austerity would make things worse but on the actual behaviour of the agencies that decide and influence policy. It is not too much to say that, as a result, an “agonising reappraisal” of neo-classical orthodoxy is now under way.
The first and in many ways most significant shift in thinking has been highlighted as the world’s major central banks have changed direction in a hugely significant and similar way. The US Federal Reserve, for example, has pursued a massive programme of “quantitative easing” (a more acceptable term than “printing money” but describing the same phenomenon); a large proportion of the US$3.7 trillions of new money has gone to inflate asset values and especially stocks, but the increase in purchasing power and therefore in demand in the wider economy has also helped to engineer a welcome recovery in American employment and output.
What is significant about this quantitative easing, however, is that it goes beyond a Keynesian readiness to borrow in order to finance new economic activity. Instead, it represents a new willingness to use monetary policy in a quite different way. Instead of allowing the retail banks to exercise a virtually exclusive monopoly power over the creation of new money for their own purposes, the Federal Reserve has seen the possibility – not to say, the necessity – of using the fiat power of government to produce the new money that the economy needs. This is a flat denial not only of austerity as the proper response to recession but also of the whole basis of the monetarist policy practised over four decades. Other major central banks have taken note.
The Bank of England has also practised quantitative easing on a large scale (up to £350 billion, albeit that most of it went to shore up the banks) and broke new ground when, in a paper published in the Quarterly Bulletin of March last year, it conceded (the first such concession by any major central bank) that 97% of the money in circulation in the UK was created out of nothing by the banks, in the form of credit provided largely for house purchase. Significantly, the injection of so much new money – just as in the case of the US – made no discernible difference to inflation. Again, the Bank of England’s action represents a tacit admission that monetary policy is no longer just a rather ineffectual way of trying to control inflation – something that is thought to turn essentially on the interest rates charged by banks for the purpose of lending on mortgage – but is potentially an important instrument in the hands of governments for encouraging and facilitating economic growth.
That instrument, if properly understood, could be yet more effective if the new money created by central banks – or rather by central banks at the behest of governments – was directed specifically to productive investment, rather than applied to rebuilding the banks’ balance sheets (as in the UK) or to raising the general level of demand (as in the US). That is precisely the point taken by the Bank of Japan; under the policy decided by Shinzo Abe’s government, the BoJ’s creation of new money has not been spread across the economy in an undirected fashion but has been earmarked exclusively for investment in new productive capacity. In following this course, Abe is consciously following the precepts laid down by the great Keynesian economist Osamu Shimomura, widely recognised in Japan as the father of the Japanese economic miracle of the 1960s and 1970s but virtually unknown in the West.
Shimomura understood and applied two of Keynes’ great insights – first, that there is no intrinsic reason for a scarcity of capital, and secondly, that an increase in the money supply cannot be inflationary if the increased production that it is designed to produce actually materialises. The huge expansion in post-war Japanese industrial production was largely financed, not by taxation revenue or government borrowing, but by credit created by the Bank of Japan and focused on productive investment. China today has followed a similar course. As John Kenneth Galbraith remarked “The process by which banks create money is so simple that the mind is repelled”. Or, as a modern writer on monetary policy (Joe Guinan) says, “the notion of a revenue-constrained government budget in a monetarily sovereign state (is)… a useful fiction for conservatives and rentiers.”
Perhaps the most dramatic reversal of the austerity mindset, however, has been the abandonment this year by the European Central Bank of its destructive austerity stance and its resort to the printing presses – stirred to action no doubt by the threat of deflation in the euro zone and the results of the Greek election. The willingness of the ECB to change course in this way, in the face of continued opposition to this decision from Angela Merkel and the German government, shows just how compelling the ECB found the arguments for doing just that.
Smaller central banks have adopted similar changes in approach. In New Zealand, for example, the Reserve Bank, timidly enough, has begun to recognise through its willingness to use macro-prudential measures such as tighter loan-to-value ratios that monetary policy is a very different beast from what it has been thought to be by orthodox monetarists over the last three or four decades.
It is not just central banks who have had second thoughts. Many leading economists have also begun to think afresh about these issues. A school of economic thought called Modern Monetary Theory promotes the idea that monetary policy could and should have a much more important role than simply restraining inflation, and that it could when properly applied act as a major stimulus to economic growth. Leading British economists like Adair Turner, who was a leading member of the Bank of England’s Financial Policy Committee, have advocated the use of what has often in the past pejoratively been called “helicopter money” as a means of aiding recovery from recession. Professor Richard Werner of Southampton University, following a detailed analysis of the Japanese experience of periods of both growth and stagnation, has urged the significance of credit-creation as an economic factor. Nobel Prize-winners like Paul Krugman and Joseph Stiglitz have argued consistently against austerity. New thinking of this kind and an increased understanding of the role of banks and of credit creation have also attracted attention and support from leading economic journalists like Martin Wolf of the Financial Times.
As this shift in expert opinion gathers weight, even the major international bodies are beginning to abandon the orthodoxy that has governed the global economy for more than thirty years. The IMF has now withdrawn its support for the austerity policies it initially recommended as the antidote to recession in the years following the Global Financial Crisis. And the OECD has recently published an important report in which it finds that the inequality that Thomas Piketty has argued is the inevitable consequence of a free-market economy is a deterrent to, rather than a necessary pre-condition of, economic growth and efficiency.
We can of course expect a determined rearguard action from the proponents of neo-classical orthodoxy. There are too many vested interests, defending fortunes and reputations, to allow for an overnight conversion to the new reality on the part of the world’s economic establishment. The experience of the 1930s shows that old certainties are abandoned only with difficulty and after a lengthy period during which the dust clears and a new understanding is gained by virtue of a longer perspective.
We may, in other words, now be at a moment in history when a clearer idea as to what went wrong so as to produce the Global Financial Crisis and what has then been needed to recover from recession is gradually but increasingly commanding assent. The disappointing aspect of this glacially slow process is that it is the politicians, and even politicians of the left, who are dragging their feet. It is remarkable that it seems to be the much-derided bankers, economists and officials who are casting aside their blinkers and moving forward, while the politicians are still shying at ghosts and are in thrall to outworn dogma.
It seems that those seeking popular endorsement are still terrified of being seen as irresponsible and are therefore unable to break free of the supposed constraints demanded by orthodoxy – the primacy of the government deficit as an economic goal, the limited role for government and of monetary policy, the supposed infallibility of the market – and that inhibit a sensible and constructive economic policy. If the central banks, the international economic organisations and an increasing number of leading economists are able to think for themselves and to learn the lessons of experience, why shouldn’t our political leaders show a little more courage and intelligence?
Bryan Gould
22 February 2015.