• Bank Profits and House Prices

    So, here’s a starter for ten. What’s the connection between the ANZ Bank’s recently announced $655 million half-yearly profit and the growing crisis of housing unaffordability in Auckland?

    It’s a question that is rarely asked. All sorts of answers are proffered to explain Auckland’s housing crisis, but almost all are answers to the wrong questions. No one bothers to ask the obvious and central question – where does the money to fund the rise and rise in house prices actually come from?

    Instead, the explanations offered generally reflect the political prejudices of those providing them. The government is anxious to blame a shortage of supply and – since this failure of the supposedly infallible market to achieve equilibrium cannot be admitted – it must be attributed to “rigidities” that prevent the market from operating properly.

    Those “rigidities” can easily, it seems, be identified. They arise, it is argued, because of local government bureaucracy and the requirements of the Resource Management Act. The answer is to remove these impediments and free up more land so that private developers can build more houses for profit.

    This supposed remedy has the great advantage of not only cutting local government down to size, but also of providing valuable profit-making opportunities to the government’s supporters in property development.

    The Opposition agrees that market failure and a shortage of supply are to blame and that the remedy is to build more houses; but, instead of waiting for property developers to sniff out profit-making opportunities, their answer is to use the power of government, both central and local, to ensure that the required houses are built at affordable prices.

    Yet others take a more technical and less political approach, pointing to failures in planning and transport policy and bemoaning the irrationality of waiting for the “free market” to do its irresponsible and inadequate best to resolve the problems.

    Most are agreed that those problems are the result of market failure. No one, it seems, bothers to ask whether the housing market is really just another market, operating according to the normal laws of supply and demand or whether, on the contrary, it doesn’t exhibit such unusual characteristics as to make it completely atypical.

    The housing market is, after all, like no other. The asset that is traded provides an essential element of life and valuable utility – a place to live. It retains and often increases its value over generations, rather than – as with most commodities – being consumed or otherwise losing value with the passage of time.

    Most importantly, it involves an asset for whose purchase many people are able to command resources far in excess of their purchasing power in respect of any other commodity. Today’s house prices could not have reached anything remotely like their current level if it were not for the fact that purchasers are able to raise large sums on mortgage, secured by the assurance that – when they come to sell (or the bank forecloses) – other purchasers will be able to do likewise.

    The constant availability of mortgage finance at ever-increasing levels is, in other words, the central element in the structure of house prices. And we get closer to understanding the problem when we recall the hugely significant change that occurred three decades ago in the way mortgage finance was provided.

    Up until that point, mortgage finance was largely provided by building societies – mutual societies which relied for the funds they lent for house purchase on the savings provided to them by their members. But in the 1980s, the building societies demutualised and became trading companies. Even more importantly, they were muscled aside by the banks which rapidly discovered that lending on mortgage was easy, secure and extremely profitable.

    The new dominance of the banks in mortgage lending was given added significance by a power that the banks have and building societies did not. Whereas the building societies were limited by the resources made available to them by lenders, the banks suffered no such constraint. They were able to create mortgage finance out of nothing, by the stroke of a pen. There was virtually no limit as to how much they could lend, provided that there was adequate security for the loans they made. And that problem – adequate security – was easily taken care of because they could simply go on lending to new generations of borrowers and purchasers who could afford, with the banks’ help, to pay the ever-inflating prices.

    The banks had discovered a huge machine for generating profits. They could charge interest on money they themselves created, and they could ensure that their lending was virtually risk-free by virtue of their willingness to go on lending so that prices (and the value of the assets that provided their security) kept on rising.

    This change – the most important change in our monetary conditions for generations – is only dimly understood. The Reserve Bank, however, is becoming uncomfortably aware of the instability of the situation we find ourselves in. If the banks should suddenly encounter a downturn and incur significant bad debts, and house prices turned down rather than up, the whole ramshackle structure could come tumbling down. Others can see that huge bank profits – removed from our economy and transferred back to Australia – are a heavy burden for our balance of payments. Yet others understand that the asset inflation in the housing market is the major source of inflation and a huge driver of widening inequality, as those who can access mortgage finance prosper and others are left behind.

    The Bank of England has recently conceded that 97% of all money in the UK is created out of nothing by bank lending and the greater part of that goes on house purchase. We are in exactly that same situation; there is no solution to housing unaffordability until the banks are made to behave more responsibly.

    Bryan Gould

    7 May 2015.

     

     

2 Comments

  1. Brendon Harre says: May 7, 2015 at 9:44 amReply

    Below is a series of comments from interest.co.nz that in some ways confirm that banks mortgage securities ‘is not as safe as houses’! : )

    http://www.interest.co.nz/opinion/75347/if-it-believes-its-own-words-government-should-be-prepared-take-centralised-control

    by Brendon | Wed, 06/05/2015 – 23:37

    If it isn’t about supply why is that a government that didn’t mind stepping on some toes could buy a few farms for say $50K a hectare, maybe using compulsory purchase powers. The price such it allows the farmer to buy another equivalent or better farm. This land being located in some future greenfield transport hubs, North, West or South of Auckland. Build medium density housing of 20 houses per hectare. With the houses contracted out to be built by the private sector.

    Costs per house.
    Land $2500
    3 waters/ subdivision dev. $80,000
    Build cost -3 bedroom/single garage $220,000
    Upgrade transport to hub $50,000

    All up cost $350,000 for a modest home that should be affordable to the median buyer.

    Tell me why this supply solution wouldn’t work?

    by steven | Thu, 07/05/2015 – 07:44
    up
    3 users have voted, including you.
    It would as much as anything would. However no Government is willing to do this. Plus once the TPPA is signed destroying a land owners ability to make huge profits will result in a dispute. It would be interesting to see just how much land is banked around Auckland by foreigners btw, quite a bit I suspect.

    Not sure where you get the transport hub costings from but light rails is $4500 or more per metre, so a 20km line is $90million+ plus extra for stations I think, spead across how many houses? not 20 that is for sure. 20,000 now, well yes, then its about $5000 per house. Plus then roads, a fairly decent road would be needed, I odnt have the cost per metre for that. If you are going to do this then really there is a case for a MUD actually, that way the entire cost of all the services are met by the owners of those 20,000 houses.

    Personally I think the Govn since it can borrow very cheaply for 10 years (4.5%?) should do so and do the work itself and let it run and not put impossible criteria and expectations on the council(s).

    Actually I think the Govn could and should do a compulsory purchase most NZers would have no issues I suspect, but dogma will stop this present Govn if nothing else. Then hand it over as a MUD with say a 20 year right of income.

    by Brendon | Thu, 07/05/2015 – 20:23

    20,000 houses x $50,000 contribution towards a transport hub/link upgrade = $1 billion.

    That should be plenty for some pretty impressive transport infrastructure!

    20,000 houses with a density of 20 houses per hectare consumes 1000 hectares (one big or a few small farms). That would be a circular urban area with a 1.8km radius.

    If there were light rail/ express busway station(s) everybody would be in biking/walking distance.

    by Simon | Thu, 07/05/2015 – 10:57

    who buys it at 350k? When its market value would immediately be 650-700k? Its equivalent to gifting someone 300k. Not very fair.

Trackbacks for this post

  1. NZ’s Coming Financial Crunch | Kapiti Independent

Leave a reply.