• The Mark-Time Budget

    The fact that this week’s budget will do no more than mark time should come as no surprise. We now have getting on for three years’ experience of a government whose idea of managing the economy is simply to wait to see what turns up.

    Some of what has turned up has not been very helpful. The Christchurch earthquakes, in particular, plus the collapse of a couple of dozen finance companies, have not made things any easier. The government, of course, has seized on these factors to explain why their do-nothing policy has not produced better results.

    But other developments have been very advantageous. World commodity prices – and prices for our commodities in particular – have soared to record levels. Our major export markets – Australia and China – have been the two economies that have best been able to shrug off the global recession. Our Australian-owned banks, while having to grapple with the higher cost of international borrowing, have ensured that we have been largely insulated against the global financial crisis.

    And, as independent agencies like the IMF and Standard and Poor’s have made clear, (and has been conveniently ignored by media who prefer to focus for their own reasons on the government’s deficit) our public finances are – both historically and comparatively – in a reasonably healthy state, reflecting the prudent management and repayment of public debt carried out by earlier Finance Ministers.

    These factors should surely have meant that we, too, like our two major trading partners, were able to rebound from recession and resume a rate of growth that would restore something like full employment and – with higher tax revenues – achieve an immediate improvement in the government’s accounts. But, disappointingly, having fallen into recession before most other countries, we are still bumping along on the bottom.

    Economies are robust things. You can kick them, neglect them, starve them, but sooner or later their natural buoyancy will bring about a recovery of sorts. But that recovery will be longer delayed, and will be from a lower base and less strong and sustainable than it should have been.

    The failure to get the economy moving is in other words not a cost-free dereliction of duty. Over a three-year period, the failure to move forward could well have cost us up to $20 billion in lost national income and will mean that growth, when it does resume, will be from a lower base and on a lower trajectory – penalising us for years to come.

    Many remain without work, many more are worse off, our public services are underfunded, our investment in our future is undermined, our ability to protect our environment is weakened, all because recession continues to hold us in its grip.

    We can ill afford such a loss. Little wonder that Australian living standards continue to outpace ours (as the current disparity in the value of our respective currencies makes clear) and that the exodus across the Tasman is again gathering pace.

    One does not need to support Act to have some sympathy with Don Brash when, faced with government by inertia, he accuses the Prime Minister of taking no action to grapple with our problems – which is not to say that the good doctor’s prescriptions would not make matters a good deal worse.

    We may be grateful that the Prime Minister declines to follow Don Brash’s advice but why does he not bestir himself of his own accord? It is partly a matter of political calculation. The Prime Minister no doubt reasons that he continues to do well in the opinion polls without doing anything, so why take the risk?

    But it is also a matter of experience and temperament. Many voters will have concluded, when John Key became Prime Minister, that the economy was in safe hands. A self-made millionaire would certainly know a thing or two about what makes the economy tick.

    But experience in the frenetic and short-term world of the foreign currency trader – a world of snap judgments and overnight deals – is not necessarily the best preparation for managing a whole economy at the macro level over a long period. That requires something very different.

    And John Key has another characteristic, which he shares with my former colleague, Tony Blair. His basic pitch to the electorate is that he is a nice guy who can be trusted to take the pain out of politics – and, to some degree, the politics out of politics. A winning smile and a telegenic personality – both possessed in large measure by both Blair and Key – will get you a long way; but that advantage is put at risk when hard decisions have to be made and people are disappointed.

    We need a budget this week that faces the tough issues, that sets us on course to save and invest, to reduce our national indebtedness, and to improve the competitiveness of our productive sector – and to use the comparative strength of the government’s finances to help us achieve these goals. It seems unlikely that we will get it.

    Bryan Gould

    14 May 2011

    This article was published in the NZ Herald on 17 May

  • The Chinese Challenge

    An Economic Miracle

    I first went to China in 1978 as a member of a British Parliamentary delegation. We were the first Western politicians to be invited into China following the fall of the Gang of Four.

    The trip was like visiting the moon. The country was unlike anything I had ever seen. Literally everyone wore drab-coloured Mao tunics. The only cars were heavy black Soviet-made limousines that ferried senior Party officials around Beijing; otherwise, everyone rode bicycles.

    There were no shops, apart from the handful of Friendship Stores that were open exclusively to foreign dignitaries and diplomats. Otherwise, the only signs of commerce were the mounds of cabbages and pumpkins piled up on street corners and brought to makeshift markets by peasants from the countryside.

    There was no colour anywhere, apart from huge red banners proclaiming the Five Modernisations. It was impossible to escape the blare of loudspeakers, broadcasting party propaganda, on trains, in streets and from poles in the fields. When we ventured out of our state-run hotel (also restricted to foreign visitors) in the evening, we would attract large crowds who had never before seen a white face.

    I returned to China in 1995 as the Vice-Chancellor of Waikato University and thereafter visited it once or twice a year for a period of eight or nine years. The transformation from 1978 was astonishing. Vast new infrastructure projects were being undertaken. Popular wisdom had it that 20% of the world’s cranes could be found in Shanghai over this period. Huge areas of traditional housing were swept away to make way for motorways and new industrial and commercial development. I recall travelling in to Wuhan from the airport along a newly opened, multi-lane motorway and my taxi having to avoid peasants walking towards us with donkey carts, so unfamiliar were they with what a motorway was.

    That transformation has continued apace. The rest of the world has been astonished by the speed with which China has taken its place as a major economic power. China has, at a time of recession for the rest of the world economy, maintained an annual growth rate over recent years averaging 10%.

    Just this year, with nominal GDP of US$5.8786 trillion, China has overtaken Japan as the world’s second largest economy, having overtaken Germany for third place four years ago; it is on track to overtake the United States by 2030. China will become the world’s largest producer of manufactured goods, surpassing the United States, this year. It is already by far the world’s largest car manufacturer, with a total production nearly twice that of Japan, and two and a half times that of the United States.

    China’s trade surplus in 2010 was US$185 billion but was as high as US$295 billion in 2008. In a decade, China’s share of world trade has grown from 4% to 10%. China became the world’s largest exporter, overtaking Germany, in 2009. China’s foreign exchange reserves now total US$2.454 trillion, nearly 50% of GDP, even after huge overseas investment over recent years. That means that the Chinese economy is now sitting on a massive war chest that allows it to buy up major assets, from mineral reserves to new technology to farming land, from around the world.

    It is not just on the production side that the Chinese economy has achieved a new dominance. China is now the world’s largest car market and the biggest energy consumer. Inward foreign direct investment totalled US$105 billion in 2010 and Chinese outward foreign direct investment now totals US$261.5 billion; both totals are growing fast.

    The scale and speed of Chinese economic development up till now is impressive enough. But future development may be even more significant. China accounts, of course, for a fifth of the world’s population, but Chinese GDP per capita is at present only about one fifth that of Japan, once purchasing power parities are taken into account. This gives some idea of the potential for future growth that Chinese leaders will now have in their sights.

    A New Solution To A Political Conundrum

    While the economic development is the most eye-catching aspect of the transformation, the student of politics will also find much to marvel at. China has succeeded where the Soviet Union failed, by finding a way to combine a centrally directed economy and a monolithic political structure with the innovation and enterprise that only a market economy can provide.

    Mao Tse Tung had recognised the Soviet failure – the extent to which the Soviet economy had succumbed to sclerosis, and Soviet society had become stultified. Mao’s solution to the problem of maintaining a rigid central political control while stimulating renewal and innovation was the Cultural Revolution – an attempt to ensure that the party organisation was never allowed to become a dead weight – but the cure proved to be worse than the disease.

    Following Mao’s death and the fall of the Gang of Four, however, Deng Xiaoping initiated a new approach, in which the Chinese Communist Party maintained its central political control, and set the broad framework of macro-economic policy, but – within that framework – allowed private enterprise to flourish. The consequence has been that a large element in China’s economic growth has been the prospect for many entrepreneurs of becoming very rich. China is now home to more billionaires than anywhere else. There are perhaps 120 million Chinese, living largely on the eastern seaboard, who enjoy living standards comparable to those of the prosperous Western middle class.

    It is, though, a version of private enterprise that we are unfamiliar with in the West. It is a private enterprise that is self-consciously an arm of government policy, but which – in return for complying faithfully with that policy – is free to pursue its own interests. The key is that the Chinese seem to have recognised that government and private enterprise can interact to their mutual advantage, each doing what it is best equipped to do, each contributing to the achievement of the goals of the other.

    Does The West Have All The Answers?

    In the West, of course, dominated as we are by an Anglo-American model of capitalism, a close and symbiotic relationship between government and the private sector such as the Chinese have achieved is regarded as anathema. The Western view has been that the best thing government can do for industry is to “get off our backs”. Government intervention is almost invariably seen as unhelpful; “second guessing” an infallible market will always produce worse results, it is said, than if it had been left to itself.

    Regulation of the market place is seen as unnecessary and sure to be self-defeating. And even those traditional spheres of governmental responsibility and activity – like infrastructure investment, or the provision of public services like education or prisons – are increasingly being colonised by private investors and providers. The role of government in providing and guaranteeing the essential building blocks of economic success –essential physical and technological infrastructure, a safe environment in which to do business, an educated and motivated workforce, a proper level of advanced research – is discounted.

    In the United Kingdom, for example, the proudly proclaimed goal of the newly elected coalition government is to “shrink the state”. In the United States, the Obama administration struggles to identify, let alone apply, the lessons from the global financial crisis. In a small economy like New Zealand, which has experimented for nearly three decades with an extreme free-market policy, there is no disposition to recognise its failures. Blind faith is still reposed in the magical ability of the “free market” to deliver salvation.

    New Zealand has, in fact, been one of the economies most driven by free-market ideology. Despite the overwhelming evidence of the New Zealand economy’s lack of competitiveness, as witness a trade deficit that – despite our small size – is the 13th biggest in the world and almost certainly the biggest per capita, and our sad record of having sold off a higher proportion of our national assets to overseas owners than any other comparable country, we are still ready to sign up to new free trade agreements which hand over major powers to foreign corporations and cede yet more control and loss of national wealth to foreign owners. And domestically, our government continues to cut back on public spending and to privatise anything that shows sign of life.

    Much of the ideology, of course, that dictates that governments must stay out of business is a sham. A close relationship between government and business is regarded as highly desirable – even in a country like the United States – provided that it is business that dictates to government rather than the other way round. The nexus between government and the US defence industry is a case in point.

    The Role of Government – China Style

    There can hardly be a starker contrast than with the approach followed by the Chinese government. To explore that contrast, and to ask the obvious questions, is not to endorse or commend all or even any of what the Chinese have done and are doing. But it is surely prudent to recognise that the Chinese have achieved an economic performance that is already world-beating and that is likely to overwhelm us if – as is likely – it continues to develop, and that they have done so while pursuing a very different political and ideological approach from our own. No dispassionate observer, comparing our recent history and immediate prospects with those of China, could possibly say that we can have nothing to learn from the Chinese.

    So, how have the Chinese done it? In many respects, there is no mystery. A government that has virtually guaranteed stability and continuity is able to take a long strategic view. A government that sees little need to curry favour with voters or with particular interest groups has been free to pursue a single-minded objective – the economic development of the country. A government that can take decisions, irrespective of the civil or property rights of individual citizens, has been able to plan and decide solely in accordance with those economic goals

    They have used that freedom of decision and action to be quite ruthless and have accordingly attracted severe criticism from trade partners. A case in point has been their policy on the foreign exchange value of their currency. The Chinese renminbi is still not fully convertible and its value is accordingly established by the direction of the Chinese government. By pegging its value to the US dollar, they have been able to take advantage, in terms of the competitive pricing of their exports, of the fall in the dollar’s value.

    There can be little doubt that the renminbi is substantially undervalued and that that is a deliberate element in Chinese trade policy. The size and persistence of the Chinese trade surplus is incontrovertible evidence of that undervaluation. The situation is reminiscent of the German and Japanese trade surpluses before the Second World War which Keynes and others correctly characterised as a powerful and aggressive assault on the economic power of the United States and Great Britain. Keynes was clear that the creditor countries were as much to blame as debtor countries for the trade imbalances that threatened world peace.

    China was of course admitted to membership of the World Trade Organisation in 2001, and it might have been expected that we would see some moderation in the aggressive element in trade policy that the undervaluation of the currency represents. That does not seem to have materialised, and the Chinese have continued to strongly resist pressure from the United States in particular to revalue their currency.

    Manipulating the currency is just one example of government intervention in economic policy and in wider strategic matters. It is safe to say that, in marked contrast to the New Zealand government’s attitude that the national interest can safely be left to market forces, the Chinese government has a well-developed strategic view as to where the national economy can and should develop and literally every economic actor in China is required to comply with that strategy.

    So, the domestic programme of infrastructure development is highly planned. Transport, physical and electronic communications, energy supplies, scientific research, education across the board, are all integrated parts of a wider strategy. They are all publicly funded as part of a coherent programme of economic development. That programme is given practical effect as a matter of national priority; individual interests that might conflict with that priority are simply swept aside in a way that would be unacceptable in a Western democracy.

    The Chinese government takes full responsibility for macro-economic policy. It determines monetary policy (principally interest rates) and controls exchange rates and capital flows in and out of the country. It relies greatly on fiscal policy – principally public spending levels and taxation – to control inflation and to target sustainable growth rates. It exercises close control over the Chinese banking system. It pays particular attention to the competitiveness of Chinese production – the key to their export success and growth rates – which is, of course, where controlling the international value of the currency assumes great importance.

    This is all of course quite different from the attitude of Western governments. In line with the general antipathy to allowing or recognising either the actuality or possibility that governments might be able to help strategically in identifying what is needed for economic success, macro-economic policy is almost totally ignored in Western countries. What passes for macro-economic policy (and the term itself is almost regarded as a dirty word) is limited to delegating to unelected and therefore unaccountable bankers the responsibility for fixing interest rates as part of a narrowly focused emphasis on controlling inflation; everything else is left to the market.

    While New Zealand – against all the evidence and common sense – sees great advantage to opening up our small, vulnerable and uncompetitive economy to all-comers, while hardly bothering to secure any safeguards for domestic industry, the Chinese attitude to regulating trade relations is a further example of a quite different approach. The Chinese take a strictly self-interested approach in deciding what goods can be imported and on what terms. The export effort is carefully directed. The currency is not fully convertible and capital flows in and out of the country are closely regulated. It is no accident that the first Western country with which China concluded a free trade deal was New Zealand – a country which was too small to pose any threat and was seen as a useful test-bed on which to sort out the possible wrinkles that free trade might bring with it.

    The Chinese government intervenes as a matter of course in other areas as well. It has a clear industrial strategy; unlike the West, where “picking winners” is widely dismissed as futile and counter-productive, the Chinese have no doubt as to where those winners are needed. Huge public resources are put into developing leading-edge technology – and if they cannot wait to develop it themselves, they buy it or acquire it by less scrupulous means. So, the essential building blocks for future development are clearly identified and targeted, and are then either supported from the public purse or entrusted to private firms which are required to meet the goals set for them.

    The labour supply is a further element which is clearly recognised as a governing element in future economic development. Great attention is paid to the skills needed by the labour force in a modern economy – not only to the higher-level research and technological skills but also to the general level of education of the workforce as a whole. The Chinese government is well aware that it has so far brought into the sphere of a modern competitive economy only about 10% of its potential total workforce.

    The Chinese have in other words a virtually inexhaustible source of cheap labour waiting for the chance to become more productive. The Hong Kong economy of the last quarter of last century offers a telling example – on a much smaller scale – of how valuable the constant underpinning and renewing of a developing economy through a supply of cheap labour (in their case, by virtue of illegal immigration across the border with China) can be. Low wage rates and therefore price competitiveness can be maintained at the bottom end of the labour market, even while growing development and competitiveness are raising living standards and wage rates at the higher end. The Chinese government will be well aware of this trump card in their hand.

    In planning the future course of Chinese economic development, the Chinese government takes, in other words, a coherent long-term strategic view which is quite foreign (and almost repugnant) to Western governments and business leaders. They control and direct (to a degree that would be unacceptable in the West) a population that is well-educated and hard-working and that represents a fifth of the world’s population. They have an immense potential for further development, in terms of a huge supply of cheap but well-educated labour, unmatchable competitiveness, substantial natural resources, a well directed and financed research effort, and large and growing war chest of foreign exchange reserves. And they believe that developing a strategic approach to deploying these assets to the best advantage is a central responsibility of government.

    Planning for the Future

    It is a fair bet, however, that Chinese leaders do not take it for granted that these advantages will produce the outcomes they want. If the Chinese are to achieve the living standards they want for a fifth of the world’s population – standards comparable to those in the West – they are going to need access to a much larger share of the world’s resources than they currently command. And a greater share of the world’s resources for China means a smaller share for others.

    The resources they need now and will need even more in the future if they are to achieve their goals are in most cases finite – minerals and agricultural land to name but two examples. The Chinese leaders will calculate that it is not enough to sign trade deals or conclude contracts to buy the products they need. They do not wish to risk taking their chances in a competitive bidding war. If their future development is to be guaranteed, they need to do more than acquire access just to the products themselves; what is needed is control over and ownership of the means of production themselves. And the best time to achieve that access and guarantee it into the future is to buy it now, when assets in most western economies are relatively cheap and when China itself is cash-rich.

    To recognise this is not to criticise. China is entitled to compete and compete hard with western countries for what the Chinese will see as a fairer distribution of the world’s resources. But we should be under no illusion that that is the Chinese game plan.

    It should come as no surprise, therefore, to see a huge Chinese effort around the world to buy up not just outputs but the means of production of key strategic assets. The phenomenon has even attracted the attention of fiction writers. The Man From Beijing, a recent book by the Danish crime writer, Henning Mankell, takes as its theme a high-level Chinese attempt to buy, in effect, a poor African country.

    Real life provides substance to underpin this fantasy. Chinese outward foreign direct investment is rising fast and will go on rising. Nearly 20% of the US$227 billion total Chinese outward foreign direct investment was made in 2009, all the more remarkable in view of the overall fall in global FDI in that year.

    That investment is clearly targeted at particular areas. One focus is industrial capacity – particularly high-tech capacity – in the United States. The investment effort involves government-owned Sovereign Wealth Funds and State Owned Enterprises, as well as private companies with undeclared links to government.

    It is even more obviously focused on mineral resources in Australia, where Chinese investment has increased dramatically. The Australians have become increasingly wary of such investment; a Chinese bid, for example, to gain control of the world’s largest deposit of rare earths was blocked in 2009 by the Australian Foreign Investment Review Board. China already controls 95% of the world’s rare earth reserves; rare earths are an essential element in much modern electronic communication technology.

    New Zealand on the Shopping List?

    The investment effort extends beyond Australia (where Chinese purchases of Australian farms have risen tenfold) even to a small economy like New Zealand, where Chinese interest in food production has risen significantly. Some Chinese efforts to buy up not just dairy products but dairy farms and production processes in New Zealand have attracted considerable attention. The high-profile bid for the Crafar farms (20 dairy farms that are now in receivership) by the Chinese company, Natural Dairy, is a case in point. Public anxiety, as well as the obvious deficiencies of the bidders in terms of simple business reliability, led to approval for this deal being refused by the Overseas Investment Office. Significantly, however, as soon as one Chinese bidder was sent packing, another immediately took its place; that second bid is now being considered.

    The Crafar farms are not the only instance of increased Chinese interest in New Zealand agricultural production capacity. New Zealand’s leading farming services company, PGG Wrightson, is currently in the process of deciding whether or not to accept a Chinese takeover bid. And there are other instances that, by flying under the radar, have been brought to a conclusion without controversy or even public awareness.

    How many people registered, for example, that Synlait Ltd, a significant New Zealand company with a $237 million turnover, employing 195 staff and manufacturing specialist milk powders, was the target last year of a successful $82 million bid for a 51% controlling shareholding from Bright Dairy and Food Company, China’s third largest dairy company?

    It might be argued that there is no reason to distinguish Chinese investment from other overseas interest in New Zealand assets. But that is not quite true. Chinese investment in major New Zealand industrial firms like Fisher and Paykel or Mainfreight may pass without comment but the Crafar farms again provide an instructive example of how some investments differ from others.

    What distinguished the failed Natural Dairy bid was the comprehensiveness of what was proposed. The purchase of the farms was just one element in a total process which would take dairy production off Chinese-owned farms to be processed in Chinese-owned factories in New Zealand and then transported directly to be marketed to Chinese consumers.

    The farms would remain physically in New Zealand, and some local labour would be employed; but, to all intents and purposes, that element of New Zealand’s dairy production would have been integrated into the Chinese economy. The farms might as well have been re-located in Zhejiang province. Ownership of the land and of its production, decisions as to what that production might be and where it might be sold, the wealth it produced for its owners, would all have passed into Chinese hands.

    The Crafar farms represent, of course, only a tiny proportion of New Zealand’s dairy industry. But the case throws up in stark fashion the kinds of issues that can and will arise if we ignore the true significance of what is happening.

    The Chinese Government’s Hidden Hand?

    Anxiety about the activities of Chinese firms in such instances is of course increased by the close but murky connections between the strategic goals of the Chinese government on the one hand and the purely commercial objectives of Chinese companies on the other hand. Such connections between government and commerce are not unknown in the West, but most international trade deals attempt to establish “level playing fields” and therefore outlaw supposedly commercial proposals which are in reality subsidised means of achieving governmental objectives.

    Yet, it is clear that much of what passes for commercial activity by Chinese firms is in fact part of a government-directed strategy. The huge increase for example, in the number of Chinese firms bidding successfully for major infrastructure projects around the world is certainly a function of the interest that the Chinese government takes in securing such contracts. The suspicion must be that some such firms are set up specifically to obtain overseas contracts as a means of extending Chinese influence, particularly in developing countries.

    Chinese firms are often able to offer favourable prices and financing arrangements because their commercial operations are in effect guaranteed by cheap funding guaranteed by a virtually inexhaustible government purse. Chinese firms are already by far the biggest infrastructure contractors, with strongly entrenched dominant positions throughout Africa and in Eastern Europe in particular.

    The Chinese government is able to combine these contractual arrangements with claiming a position as significant aid donors to poor countries. They see trade, aid and influence as complementary elements in a single integrated drive to ensure that China will have the access and control it needs to claim a much greater share of the world’s resources.

    We should make the necessary adjustment in our thinking, in other words, so that we understand that a bid for a strategic asset by a Chinese firm may not be just a matter of a private firm taking advantage of a commercial opportunity. It may be part of a much wider picture in which the firm and its bid are to be seen as elements in a government-directed strategy to secure national goals. One of those goals might well be to secure under Chinese control a significant food-producing capacity and expertise, of which New Zealand’s dairy industry might contribute a small but valuable part.

    Can the Dragon Be Domesticated?

    None of this means that we should regard Chinese development as unalloyed bad news. Our concern should be to understand the Chinese situation and the nature of their policy objectives so that we can make sensible and prudent responses in our own interests. We should focus on protecting and advancing those interests, and on encouraging the Chinese to develop in a direction which creates mutual benefit rather than conflict. A naïve faith that the market will protect us may not be enough.

    The signs in this regard are not entirely discouraging. By contrast with the experience of the Great Depression, when US protectionism helped to drive the world economy into reverse, the Chinese economy has remained – through the current recession – dynamic, open and increasingly market-driven. That continued buoyancy has done much to avoid a repetition of the 1930s experience.

    New Zealand, in particular, has good reason to be grateful that it shares the Asia-Pacific region with the world’s fastest-growing economy. Having lost guaranteed markets in the United Kingdom and Europe, and struggled to replace them elsewhere, we suddenly find – through no particular merits of our own – that we have a hugely buoyant market for our goods within our own region.

    We should, of course, resist the more outrageous claims made for the free trade agreement we recently concluded with China. The much-trumpeted increase in our exports to China (which enthusiasts attribute to the free trade agreement) was actually well under way before the agreement took effect and simply reflects the rapidly rising Chinese demand for our goods over the recent period; and it is in any case more than offset by the huge increase in our imports from China which produces a substantial and growing surplus in China’s favour – the undervalued renminbi is as potent for us as it is elsewhere.

    The trick for us is to encourage the development of the Chinese market for our goods, while at the same time being alert to the Chinese propensity to seek ownership and control of our productive capacity. The task for our policy-makers is to eschew the simple-minded notion that any business is good business, and to distinguish those arrangements that serve our interests from those that do not.

    That task may not be as difficult as it seems. The Chinese will be the first to expect and accept a hard-headed approach, and they may have their own reasons for changing course, at least to some extent. The Chinese economy is at present seriously unbalanced. Odd though it may seem to Westerners (and New Zealanders in particular) accustomed to concerns about a damaging emphasis on consumption rather than exports, the Chinese have the opposite problem.

    A Chinese refusal to allow an appreciation of their currency so that their extreme and unfair competitiveness is reduced is likely to present them with an inflationary problem which will do the job for them. One way or another, we are likely to see a re-balancing of the Chinese economy, towards domestic consumption and away from exporting, over the coming years.

    A clue as to this kind of development in the future may be seen in the fact that China’s trade surplus dropped in January of this year to US$6.5 billion, the lowest in nine months. Imports leapt 51% in January, while exports grew 38%. This suggests that China, with rising living standards and an increased propensity to import, may be in the course of moving to a new phase, in which its hugely increased purchasing power is used to become an even more powerful magnet for key goods and services than it is at present.

    Nor should we forget either the example of Japan. I recall spending time in Japan in 1980, at a time when the Japanese economy looked very much like today’s Chinese economy, albeit on a smaller scale. The air was thick with predictions that Japan would overtake the United States as the world’s largest economy by the turn of the century. We now know that those predictions came to nought – and it may be that China, as it emerges from the rapid growth of its initial development phase, will also find the going increasingly tough.

    This suggests that we should concentrate on trying to ensure that China is increasingly drawn into global efforts to regulate the world economy. They have as much to gain in the l.ong term as we do from reforming the international monetary system and dealing with imbalances in particular, and from achieving environmentally sustainable development. Chinese keenness to join the WTO may be a useful pointer to the possibility of such future cooperation.

    Most importantly, we need to make sure that competition for the world’s scarce natural resources is conducted with as little conflict and misunderstanding as possible. The Chinese should be brought to see that launching a none-too-subtle direct grab for the natural and technological assets of other countries is likely to provoke a damaging backlash. The responsibility is ours, as well as China’s. It is for us to strike a proper balance between accepting China’s legitimate claim to a fair share, and our own right to continue to own our own assets and manage our own affairs. It is in everyone’s interests that we should be crystal clear on that fundamental issue.

    Bryan Gould

    28 February 2011

    This article was piublished on the NewNations website on 13 April

  • The Reserve Bank Governor

    Alan Bollard is a big man – well over six feet [around 1.9 m?] tall – but even his shoulders are not broad enough to bear the burdens placed on them. To point this out is not so much to criticise the Reserve Bank Governor as to lament the role in which he is cast.

    He is, after all, lumbered with virtually the sole responsibility for what passes in this country for macro-economic policy. He alone must decide every six weeks on the direction in which monetary policy should be taken. He is given a single instrument – interest rates – and a single target – inflation.

    Beyond that, macro-economic policy is virtually non-existent. Little matter that inflation might be low on the list of economic policy concerns, or that cutting interest rates might make little difference to anyone in an economy mired in recession. Faced with our manifold problems, the Governor- with his tiny armoury of largely irrelevant and ineffectual weapons – is on his own.

    Little wonder then that – in deciding last week what to do about interest rates – he should have opted to share the responsibility by talking to the Minister of Finance. There was after all the small matter of continuing recession, with little sign of the much-touted recovery – and on top of that, the further blow of the 22nd of February Christchurch earthquake.

    There was, however, much tut-tutting that the Governor should have opted, by consulting with his political masters, to depart from the principle of absolute independence for the Reserve Bank. Many commentators and practitioners seemed discomforted by the thought that the elected government might be asked to bear some responsibility for the fortunes of our economy.

    The doctrine that macro-economic policy is a simple matter of setting interest rates – a task entrusted exclusively to the Reserve Bank – is of course greatly convenient for government. It means, in our current situation, that they can disclaim responsibility for a recession that is now well into a fourth year. Not only is it nothing to do with them but – according to the doctrine – anything they might try to do would be counter-productive.

    The paradox is that governments that are unwilling to intervene in macro-economic policy, on the ground that the economy is best left to look after itself, are likely to end up being more interventionist than they expect. As the economy languishes because macro-economic policy settings are inappropriate, governments typically resort more and more – and with greater and greater desperation – to micro-economic intervention of various kinds.

    So, we find more and more fiddling with tax rates and labour laws, more and more target-setting and micro-management for science and research and the delivery of education at all levels, tighter and tighter limits on benefits and public spending programmes – all in an increasingly futile drive to reverse our poor productivity and declining competitiveness.

    But, surely, it will be asked, the Governor’s interest rate cut was a step in the right direction? Well, yes, it had a certain value as a psychological boost and as a small benefit to those with mortgages – but it is hardly likely to stimulate spending and investment to the point where the recovery really gets under way. That will require measures of a quite different nature and order of magnitude.

    If monetary policy was really the key to recovery, we should surely have seen it by now. We have, after all, had falling and historically low interest rates for years now, and the economy has hardly stirred. As I and others argued in 2008 and 2009, using monetary policy as the only stimulus to an economy in a recession is like pushing on a piece of string.

    The Governor has, in other words, done what he can, but what he can do is pitifully inadequate and beside the point. His recourse to involving the Minister of Finance last week suggests that he might be moving to this view as well.

    No one doubts that our problems are endemic and that the Christchurch earthquake has added to the government’s difficulties. But the failure to take any decisive action over a couple of years means that the earthquake cannot be identified as the primary cause of our problems.

    The government has in effect contented itself with trying to look after its own finances, and has been happy to let the wider economy look after itself. The paradox is that public finances are the healthiest part of our economy. Focusing primarily on getting the government’s deficit down, while ignoring the need for a whole-of-economy perspective, has reflected an ideological rather than practical priority, and has left the economy ill-equipped to grapple with its problems – among which, sadly, the consequences of the Christchurch earthquake now loom large.

    Surely governments should be held to account for what they are elected for – providing an effective stewardship of the economy – and the Governor of Reserve Bank should no longer be abandoned to his lonely and irrelevant vigil?

    Bryan Gould

    12 March 2011

    This article was published in the NZ Herald on 16 March.

  • The Chinese Challenge

    An Economic Miracle

    I first went to China in 1978 as a member of a British Parliamentary delegation. We were the first Western politicians to be invited into China following the fall of the Gang of Four.

    The trip was like visiting the moon. The country was unlike anything I had ever seen. Literally everyone wore drab-coloured Mao tunics. The only cars were heavy black Soviet-made limousines that ferried senior Party officials around Beijing; otherwise, everyone rode bicycles.

    There were no shops, apart from the handful of Friendship Stores that were open exclusively to foreign dignitaries and diplomats. Otherwise, the only signs of commerce were the mounds of cabbages and pumpkins piled up on street corners and brought to makeshift markets by peasants from the countryside.

    There was no colour anywhere, apart from huge red banners proclaiming the Five Modernisations. It was impossible to escape the blare of loudspeakers, broadcasting party propaganda, on trains, in streets and from poles in the fields. When we ventured out of our state-run hotel (also restricted to foreign visitors) in the evening, we would attract large crowds who had never before seen a white face.

    I returned to China in 1995 as the Vice-Chancellor of Waikato University and thereafter visited it once or twice a year for a period of eight or nine years. The transformation from 1978 was astonishing. Vast new infrastructure projects were being undertaken. Popular wisdom had it that 20% of the world’s cranes could be found in Shanghai over this period. Huge areas of traditional housing were swept away to make way for motorways and new industrial and commercial development. I recall travelling in to Wuhan from the airport along a newly opened, multi-lane motorway and my taxi having to avoid peasants walking towards us with donkey carts, so unfamiliar were they with what a motorway was.

    That transformation has continued apace. The rest of the world has been astonished by the speed with which China has taken its place as a major economic power. China has, at a time of recession for the rest of the world economy, maintained an annual growth rate over recent years averaging 10%.

    Just this year, with nominal GDP of US$5.8786 trillion, China has overtaken Japan as the world’s second largest economy, having overtaken Germany for third place four years ago; it is on track to overtake the United States by 2030. China will become the world’s largest producer of manufactured goods, surpassing the United States, this year. It is already by far the world’s largest car manufacturer, with a total production nearly twice that of Japan, and two and a half times that of the United States.

    China’s trade surplus in 2010 was US$185 billion but was as high as US$295 billion in 2008. In a decade, China’s share of world trade has grown from 4% to 10%. China became the world’s largest exporter, overtaking Germany, in 2009. China’s foreign exchange reserves now total US$2.454 trillion, nearly 50% of GDP, even after huge overseas investment over recent years. That means that the Chinese economy is now sitting on a massive war chest that allows it to buy up major assets, from mineral reserves to new technology to farming land, from around the world.

    It is not just on the production side that the Chinese economy has achieved a new dominance. China is now the world’s largest car market and the biggest energy consumer. Inward foreign direct investment totalled US$105 billion in 2010 and Chinese outward foreign direct investment now totals US$261.5 billion; both totals are growing fast.

    The scale and speed of Chinese economic development up till now is impressive enough. But future development may be even more significant. China accounts, of course, for a fifth of the world’s population, but Chinese GDP per capita is at present only about one fifth that of Japan, once purchasing power parities are taken into account. This gives some idea of the potential for future growth that Chinese leaders will now have in their sights.

    A New Solution To A Political Conundrum

    While the economic development is the most eye-catching aspect of the transformation, the student of politics will also find much to marvel at. China has succeeded where the Soviet Union failed, by finding a way to combine a centrally directed economy and a monolithic political structure with the innovation and enterprise that only a market economy can provide.

    Mao Tse Tung had recognised the Soviet failure – the extent to which the Soviet economy had succumbed to sclerosis, and Soviet society had become stultified. Mao’s solution to the problem of maintaining a rigid central political control while stimulating renewal and innovation was the Cultural Revolution – an attempt to ensure that the party organisation was never allowed to become a dead weight – but the cure proved to be worse than the disease.

    Following Mao’s death and the fall of the Gang of Four, however, Deng Xiaoping initiated a new approach, in which the Chinese Communist Party maintained its central political control, and set the broad framework of macro-economic policy, but – within that framework – allowed private enterprise to flourish. The consequence has been that a large element in China’s economic growth has been the prospect for many entrepreneurs of becoming very rich. China is now home to more billionaires than anywhere else. There are perhaps 120 million Chinese, living largely on the eastern seaboard, who enjoy living standards comparable to those of the prosperous Western middle class.

    It is, though, a version of private enterprise that we are unfamiliar with in the West. It is a private enterprise that is self-consciously an arm of government policy, but which – in return for complying faithfully with that policy – is free to pursue its own interests. The key is that the Chinese seem to have recognised that government and private enterprise can interact to their mutual advantage, each doing what it is best equipped to do, each contributing to the achievement of the goals of the other.

    Does The West Have All The Answers?

    In the West, of course, dominated as we are by an Anglo-American model of capitalism, a close and symbiotic relationship between government and the private sector such as the Chinese have achieved is regarded as anathema. The Western view has been that the best thing government can do for industry is to “get off our backs”. Government intervention is almost invariably seen as unhelpful; “second guessing” an infallible market will always produce worse results, it is said, than if it had been left to itself.

    Regulation of the market place is seen as unnecessary and sure to be self-defeating. And even those traditional spheres of governmental responsibility and activity – like infrastructure investment, or the provision of public services like education or prisons – are increasingly being colonised by private investors and providers. The role of government in providing and guaranteeing the essential building blocks of economic success –essential physical and technological infrastructure, a safe environment in which to do business, an educated and motivated workforce, a proper level of advanced research – is discounted.

    In the United Kingdom, for example, the proudly proclaimed goal of the newly elected coalition government is to “shrink the state”. In the United States, the Obama administration struggles to identify, let alone apply, the lessons from the global financial crisis. In a small economy like New Zealand, which has experimented for nearly three decades with an extreme free-market policy, there is no disposition to recognise its failures. Blind faith is still reposed in the magical ability of the “free market” to deliver salvation.

    New Zealand has, in fact, been one of the economies most driven by free-market ideology. Despite the overwhelming evidence of the New Zealand economy’s lack of competitiveness, as witness a trade deficit that – despite our small size – is the 13th biggest in the world and almost certainly the biggest per capita, and our sad record of having sold off a higher proportion of our national assets to overseas owners than any other comparable country, we are still ready to sign up to new free trade agreements which hand over major powers to foreign corporations and cede yet more control and loss of national wealth to foreign owners. And domestically, our government continues to cut back on public spending and to privatise anything that shows sign of life.

    Much of the ideology, of course, that dictates that governments must stay out of business is a sham. A close relationship between government and business is regarded as highly desirable – even in a country like the United States – provided that it is business that dictates to government rather than the other way round. The nexus between government and the US defence industry is a case in point.

    The Role of Government – China Style

    There can hardly be a starker contrast than with the approach followed by the Chinese government. To explore that contrast, and to ask the obvious questions, is not to endorse or commend all or even any of what the Chinese have done and are doing. But it is surely prudent to recognise that the Chinese have achieved an economic performance that is already world-beating and that is likely to overwhelm us if – as is likely – it continues to develop, and that they have done so while pursuing a very different political and ideological approach from our own. No dispassionate observer, comparing our recent history and immediate prospects with those of China, could possibly say that we can have nothing to learn from the Chinese.

    So, how have the Chinese done it? In many respects, there is no mystery. A government that has virtually guaranteed stability and continuity is able to take a long strategic view. A government that sees little need to curry favour with voters or with particular interest groups has been free to pursue a single-minded objective – the economic development of the country. A government that can take decisions, irrespective of the civil or property rights of individual citizens, has been able to plan and decide solely in accordance with those economic goals

    They have used that freedom of decision and action to be quite ruthless and have accordingly attracted severe criticism from trade partners. A case in point has been their policy on the foreign exchange value of their currency. The Chinese renminbi is still not fully convertible and its value is accordingly established by the direction of the Chinese government. By pegging its value to the US dollar, they have been able to take advantage, in terms of the competitive pricing of their exports, of the fall in the dollar’s value.

    There can be little doubt that the renminbi is substantially undervalued and that that is a deliberate element in Chinese trade policy. The size and persistence of the Chinese trade surplus is incontrovertible evidence of that undervaluation. The situation is reminiscent of the German and Japanese trade surpluses before the Second World War which Keynes and others correctly characterised as a powerful and aggressive assault on the economic power of the United States and Great Britain. Keynes was clear that the creditor countries were as much to blame as debtor countries for the trade imbalances that threatened world peace.

    China was of course admitted to membership of the World Trade Organisation in 2001, and it might have been expected that we would see some moderation in the aggressive element in trade policy that the undervaluation of the currency represents. That does not seem to have materialised, and the Chinese have continued to strongly resist pressure from the United States in particular to revalue their currency.

    Manipulating the currency is just one example of government intervention in economic policy and in wider strategic matters. It is safe to say that, in marked contrast to the New Zealand government’s attitude that the national interest can safely be left to market forces, the Chinese government has a well-developed strategic view as to where the national economy can and should develop and literally every economic actor in China is required to comply with that strategy.

    So, the domestic programme of infrastructure development is highly planned. Transport, physical and electronic communications, energy supplies, scientific research, education across the board, are all integrated parts of a wider strategy. They are all publicly funded as part of a coherent programme of economic development. That programme is given practical effect as a matter of national priority; individual interests that might conflict with that priority are simply swept aside in a way that would be unacceptable in a Western democracy.

    The Chinese government takes full responsibility for macro-economic policy. It determines monetary policy (principally interest rates) and controls exchange rates and capital flows in and out of the country. It relies greatly on fiscal policy – principally public spending levels and taxation – to control inflation and to target sustainable growth rates. It exercises close control over the Chinese banking system. It pays particular attention to the competitiveness of Chinese production – the key to their export success and growth rates – which is, of course, where controlling the international value of the currency assumes great importance.

    This is all of course quite different from the attitude of Western governments. In line with the general antipathy to allowing or recognising either the actuality or possibility that governments might be able to help strategically in identifying what is needed for economic success, macro-economic policy is almost totally ignored in Western countries. What passes for macro-economic policy (and the term itself is almost regarded as a dirty word) is limited to delegating to unelected and therefore unaccountable bankers the responsibility for fixing interest rates as part of a narrowly focused emphasis on controlling inflation; everything else is left to the market.

    While New Zealand – against all the evidence and common sense – sees great advantage to opening up our small, vulnerable and uncompetitive economy to all-comers, while hardly bothering to secure any safeguards for domestic industry, the Chinese attitude to regulating trade relations is a further example of a quite different approach. The Chinese take a strictly self-interested approach in deciding what goods can be imported and on what terms. The export effort is carefully directed. The currency is not fully convertible and capital flows in and out of the country are closely regulated. It is no accident that the first Western country with which China concluded a free trade deal was New Zealand – a country which was too small to pose any threat and was seen as a useful test-bed on which to sort out the possible wrinkles that free trade might bring with it.

    The Chinese government intervenes as a matter of course in other areas as well. It has a clear industrial strategy; unlike the West, where “picking winners” is widely dismissed as futile and counter-productive, the Chinese have no doubt as to where those winners are needed. Huge public resources are put into developing leading-edge technology – and if they cannot wait to develop it themselves, they buy it or acquire it by less scrupulous means. So, the essential building blocks for future development are clearly identified and targeted, and are then either supported from the public purse or entrusted to private firms which are required to meet the goals set for them.

    The labour supply is a further element which is clearly recognised as a governing element in future economic development. Great attention is paid to the skills needed by the labour force in a modern economy – not only to the higher-level research and technological skills but also to the general level of education of the workforce as a whole. The Chinese government is well aware that it has so far brought into the sphere of a modern competitive economy only about 10% of its potential total workforce.

    The Chinese have in other words a virtually inexhaustible source of cheap labour waiting for the chance to become more productive. The Hong Kong economy of the last quarter of last century offers a telling example – on a much smaller scale – of how valuable the constant underpinning and renewing of a developing economy through a supply of cheap labour (in their case, by virtue of illegal immigration across the border with China) can be. Low wage rates and therefore price competitiveness can be maintained at the bottom end of the labour market, even while growing development and competitiveness are raising living standards and wage rates at the higher end. The Chinese government will be well aware of this trump card in their hand.

    In planning the future course of Chinese economic development, the Chinese government takes, in other words, a coherent long-term strategic view which is quite foreign (and almost repugnant) to Western governments and business leaders. They control and direct (to a degree that would be unacceptable in the West) a population that is well-educated and hard-working and that represents a fifth of the world’s population. They have an immense potential for further development, in terms of a huge supply of cheap but well-educated labour, unmatchable competitiveness, substantial natural resources, a well directed and financed research effort, and large and growing war chest of foreign exchange reserves. And they believe that developing a strategic approach to deploying these assets to the best advantage is a central responsibility of government.

    Planning for the Future

    It is a fair bet, however, that Chinese leaders do not take it for granted that these advantages will produce the outcomes they want. If the Chinese are to achieve the living standards they want for a fifth of the world’s population – standards comparable to those in the West – they are going to need access to a much larger share of the world’s resources than they currently command. And a greater share of the world’s resources for China means a smaller share for others.

    The resources they need now and will need even more in the future if they are to achieve their goals are in most cases finite – minerals and agricultural land to name but two examples. The Chinese leaders will calculate that it is not enough to sign trade deals or conclude contracts to buy the products they need. They do not wish to risk taking their chances in a competitive bidding war. If their future development is to be guaranteed, they need to do more than acquire access just to the products themselves; what is needed is control over and ownership of the means of production themselves. And the best time to achieve that access and guarantee it into the future is to buy it now, when assets in most western economies are relatively cheap and when China itself is cash-rich.

    To recognise this is not to criticise. China is entitled to compete and compete hard with western countries for what the Chinese will see as a fairer distribution of the world’s resources. But we should be under no illusion that that is the Chinese game plan.

    It should come as no surprise, therefore, to see a huge Chinese effort around the world to buy up not just outputs but the means of production of key strategic assets. The phenomenon has even attracted the attention of fiction writers. The Man From Beijing, a recent book by the Danish crime writer, Henning Mankell, takes as its theme a high-level Chinese attempt to buy, in effect, a poor African country.

    Real life provides substance to underpin this fantasy. Chinese outward foreign direct investment is rising fast and will go on rising. Nearly 20% of the US$227 billion total Chinese outward foreign direct investment was made in 2009, all the more remarkable in view of the overall fall in global FDI in that year.

    That investment is clearly targeted at particular areas. One focus is industrial capacity – particularly high-tech capacity – in the United States. The investment effort involves government-owned Sovereign Wealth Funds and State Owned Enterprises, as well as private companies with undeclared links to government.

    It is even more obviously focused on mineral resources in Australia, where Chinese investment has increased dramatically. The Australians have become increasingly wary of such investment; a Chinese bid, for example, to gain control of the world’s largest deposit of rare earths was blocked in 2009 by the Australian Foreign Investment Review Board. China already controls 95% of the world’s rare earth reserves; rare earths are an essential element in much modern electronic communication technology.

    New Zealand on the Shopping List?

    The investment effort extends beyond Australia (where Chinese purchases of Australian farms have risen tenfold) even to a small economy like New Zealand, where Chinese interest in food production has risen significantly. Some Chinese efforts to buy up not just dairy products but dairy farms and production processes in New Zealand have attracted considerable attention. The high-profile bid for the Crafar farms (20 dairy farms that are now in receivership) by the Chinese company, Natural Dairy, is a case in point. Public anxiety, as well as the obvious deficiencies of the bidders in terms of simple business reliability, led to approval for this deal being refused by the Overseas Investment Office. Significantly, however, as soon as one Chinese bidder was sent packing, another immediately took its place; that second bid is now being considered.

    The Crafar farms are not the only instance of increased Chinese interest in New Zealand agricultural production capacity. New Zealand’s leading farming services company, PGG Wrightson, is currently in the process of deciding whether or not to accept a Chinese takeover bid. And there are other instances that, by flying under the radar, have been brought to a conclusion without controversy or even public awareness.

    How many people registered, for example, that Synlait Ltd, a significant New Zealand company with a $237 million turnover, employing 195 staff and manufacturing specialist milk powders, was the target last year of a successful $82 million bid for a 51% controlling shareholding from Bright Dairy and Food Company, China’s third largest dairy company?

    It might be argued that there is no reason to distinguish Chinese investment from other overseas interest in New Zealand assets. But that is not quite true. Chinese investment in major New Zealand industrial firms like Fisher and Paykel or Mainfreight may pass without comment but the Crafar farms again provide an instructive example of how some investments differ from others.

    What distinguished the failed Natural Dairy bid was the comprehensiveness of what was proposed. The purchase of the farms was just one element in a total process which would take dairy production off Chinese-owned farms to be processed in Chinese-owned factories in New Zealand and then transported directly to be marketed to Chinese consumers.

    The farms would remain physically in New Zealand, and some local labour would be employed; but, to all intents and purposes, that element of New Zealand’s dairy production would have been integrated into the Chinese economy. The farms might as well have been re-located in Zhejiang province. Ownership of the land and of its production, decisions as to what that production might be and where it might be sold, the wealth it produced for its owners, would all have passed into Chinese hands.

    The Crafar farms represent, of course, only a tiny proportion of New Zealand’s dairy industry. But the case throws up in stark fashion the kinds of issues that can and will arise if we ignore the true significance of what is happening.

    The Chinese Government’s Hidden Hand?

    Anxiety about the activities of Chinese firms in such instances is of course increased by the close but murky connections between the strategic goals of the Chinese government on the one hand and the purely commercial objectives of Chinese companies on the other hand. Such connections between government and commerce are not unknown in the West, but most international trade deals attempt to establish “level playing fields” and therefore outlaw supposedly commercial proposals which are in reality subsidised means of achieving governmental objectives.

    Yet, it is clear that much of what passes for commercial activity by Chinese firms is in fact part of a government-directed strategy. The huge increase for example, in the number of Chinese firms bidding successfully for major infrastructure projects around the world is certainly a function of the interest that the Chinese government takes in securing such contracts. The suspicion must be that some such firms are set up specifically to obtain overseas contracts as a means of extending Chinese influence, particularly in developing countries.

    Chinese firms are often able to offer favourable prices and financing arrangements because their commercial operations are in effect guaranteed by cheap funding guaranteed by a virtually inexhaustible government purse. Chinese firms are already by far the biggest infrastructure contractors, with strongly entrenched dominant positions throughout Africa and in Eastern Europe in particular.

    The Chinese government is able to combine these contractual arrangements with claiming a position as significant aid donors to poor countries. They see trade, aid and influence as complementary elements in a single integrated drive to ensure that China will have the access and control it needs to claim a much greater share of the world’s resources.

    We should make the necessary adjustment in our thinking, in other words, so that we understand that a bid for a strategic asset by a Chinese firm may not be just a matter of a private firm taking advantage of a commercial opportunity. It may be part of a much wider picture in which the firm and its bid are to be seen as elements in a government-directed strategy to secure national goals. One of those goals might well be to secure under Chinese control a significant food-producing capacity and expertise, of which New Zealand’s dairy industry might contribute a small but valuable part.

    Can the Dragon Be Domesticated?

    None of this means that we should regard Chinese development as unalloyed bad news. Our concern should be to understand the Chinese situation and the nature of their policy objectives so that we can make sensible and prudent responses in our own interests. We should focus on protecting and advancing those interests, and on encouraging the Chinese to develop in a direction which creates mutual benefit rather than conflict. A naïve faith that the market will protect us may not be enough.

    The signs in this regard are not entirely discouraging. By contrast with the experience of the Great Depression, when US protectionism helped to drive the world economy into reverse, the Chinese economy has remained – through the current recession – dynamic, open and increasingly market-driven. That continued buoyancy has done much to avoid a repetition of the 1930s experience.

    New Zealand, in particular, has good reason to be grateful that it shares the Asia-Pacific region with the world’s fastest-growing economy. Having lost guaranteed markets in the United Kingdom and Europe, and struggled to replace them elsewhere, we suddenly find – through no particular merits of our own – that we have a hugely buoyant market for our goods within our own region.

    We should, of course, resist the more outrageous claims made for the free trade agreement we recently concluded with China. The much-trumpeted increase in our exports to China (which enthusiasts attribute to the free trade agreement) was actually well under way before the agreement took effect and simply reflects the rapidly rising Chinese demand for our goods over the recent period; and it is in any case more than offset by the huge increase in our imports from China which produces a substantial and growing surplus in China’s favour – the undervalued renminbi is as potent for us as it is elsewhere.

    The trick for us is to encourage the development of the Chinese market for our goods, while at the same time being alert to the Chinese propensity to seek ownership and control of our productive capacity. The task for our policy-makers is to eschew the simple-minded notion that any business is good business, and to distinguish those arrangements that serve our interests from those that do not.

    That task may not be as difficult as it seems. The Chinese will be the first to expect and accept a hard-headed approach, and they may have their own reasons for changing course, at least to some extent. The Chinese economy is at present seriously unbalanced. Odd though it may seem to Westerners (and New Zealanders in particular) accustomed to concerns about a damaging emphasis on consumption rather than exports, the Chinese have the opposite problem.

    A Chinese refusal to allow an appreciation of their currency so that their extreme and unfair competitiveness is reduced is likely to present them with an inflationary problem which will do the job for them. One way or another, we are likely to see a re-balancing of the Chinese economy, towards domestic consumption and away from exporting, over the coming years.

    A clue as to this kind of development in the future may be seen in the fact that China’s trade surplus dropped in January of this year to US$6.5 billion, the lowest in nine months. Imports leapt 51% in January, while exports grew 38%. This suggests that China, with rising living standards and an increased propensity to import, may be in the course of moving to a new phase, in which its hugely increased purchasing power is used to become an even more powerful magnet for key goods and services than it is at present.

    Nor should we forget either the example of Japan. I recall spending time in Japan in 1980, at a time when the Japanese economy looked very much like today’s Chinese economy, albeit on a smaller scale. The air was thick with predictions that Japan would overtake the United States as the world’s largest economy by the turn of the century. We now know that those predictions came to nought – and it may be that China, as it emerges from the rapid growth of its initial development phase, will also find the going increasingly tough.

    This suggests that we should concentrate on trying to ensure that China is increasingly drawn into global efforts to regulate the world economy. They have as much to gain in the l.ong term as we do from reforming the international monetary system and dealing with imbalances in particular, and from achieving environmentally sustainable development. Chinese keenness to join the WTO may be a useful pointer to the possibility of such future cooperation.

    Most importantly, we need to make sure that competition for the world’s scarce natural resources is conducted with as little conflict and misunderstanding as possible. The Chinese should be brought to see that launching a none-too-subtle direct grab for the natural and technological assets of other countries is likely to provoke a damaging backlash. The responsibility is ours, as well as China’s. It is for us to strike a proper balance between accepting China’s legitimate claim to a fair share, and our own right to continue to own our own assets and manage our own affairs. It is in everyone’s interests that we should be crystal clear on that fundamental issue.

    Bryan Gould

    28 February 2011

    This article was piublished on the NewNations website on 13 April

  • The Death Spiral

    There are times when one can’t help feeling sorry for the government. After two years of framing economic policy to please the credit rating agencies – last year’s budget was virtually dictated by Standard and Poor’s – their reward has been a warning last month that our credit rating is on negative watch.

    That blow has been followed by the revelation that the government’s deficit has blown out by $2 billion more than forecast. This intrusion of economic reality may not be welcome but it has been salutary.

    The government’s response so far to these twin developments has been to maintain a stiff upper lip, and to continue to target a return to surplus by 2016. Others have not been so restrained. The air is thick with urgings – from the Reserve Bank, the Treasury, the Business Roundtable, and not least the Herald’s own leader-writers and columnists – that the government’s deficit must be cut and cut faster.

    It is hard to see these warnings as anything more than a knee-jerk reaction to what people think they heard, or wanted to hear. They see or purport to see a substantial connection between the threatened downgrading of our credit rating and the size of the government’s deficit.

    A careful reading of Standard and Poor’s statement, however, reveals that the government’s deficit (which remains perfectly manageable by international standards) played only a minor part in their expression of concern about our credit rating. Their focus was on the country’s external deficit – our propensity to finance an inflated consumption by borrowing from overseas.

    It is true that the government’s deficit is an element in the country’s overall deficit but it is not the element that is of particular concern to S&P. What worries them – and they are quite explicit about this – is that, if and when a substantial recovery finally materialises, our appetite for imported consumer goods will re-emerge with a vengeance and we will be back to our bad old habits of borrowing to finance a persistent trade deficit.

    The real import of their warning is that they see nothing in our current policy settings to suggest that we will avoid this all too familiar outcome. They fear that any revival in economic activity will see the application of the decades-old “remedy” of high interest rates leading to a yet higher dollar, with consequent damage to savings and exports while we binge on artificially cheap imports. Sooner or later, they warn, the willingness of overseas lenders to fund this rake’s progress may be exhausted.

    But, say the deficit hawks, the external deficit, our poor savings record, and the narrow base of our export sector – all of which are fingered by S&P as causes for their concern – are problems for the future. Surely – whether S&P say it or not – the one thing the government can do to help is to get its own deficit down faster than planned, even if that means painful cuts that might impact the most vulnerable?

    Let us be clear. All other things being equal, it would clearly be beneficial for the government to eliminate its deficit as soon as possible. And the government is quite right to seek savings in respect of public spending that may be wasteful or poorly directed.
    But if cutting the deficit is the first and over-riding priority, we need to be sure that it would produce, in today’s context, the desired outcomes – and it is a pity that this realisation did not dawn before the government’s finances were further weakened by tax cuts that mainly benefited the better off.

    But there is no evidence that simply taking the axe to government spending would help matters. The main reason for the government’s increased deficit is that tax revenue – already depressed by the recession – is much lower than forecast, and that in turn is a direct consequence of the slowness of our economic recovery. To cut government expenditure, thereby further depressing demand and eventually tax revenue, is not the most obvious solution to this problem.

    The paradox is that, as many of us warned at the onset of the recession, the greater the priority and urgency given to cutting the deficit, the more persistent it is likely to be. The most effective course for a government worried about its deficit is – while maintaining proper controls over potentially wasteful spending – to play its part in ensuring that the level of economic activity rises.

    As it is, we are in danger of getting caught in a downward spiral. Our export income is being depressed by the high dollar. The consumer is facing higher fuel and energy prices and the threat of continuing job losses, and uses any margin of spending power to pay down debt. The business sector is struggling with inadequate demand and therefore keeping tight tabs on employment and investment plans. If the government, too, cuts its spending further, where is recovery to come from? And how do we ensure that recovery, when it comes, does not take us straight back – as S&P warn that it will – to the problems that have dogged us for decades?

    Bryan Gould

    15 December 2010